Category: Save Our Super Articles

Money Management – No more “simpler super”

Money Management

6 October 2016

Catherine Chivers – Manager for strategic advice at Perpetual Private.

The 2016 Budget handed down on 3 May, 2016 by Treasurer Scott Morrison foreshadowed the most sweeping changes to the superannuation landscape that the Australian financial services industry has seen in close to a decade. 

In recent weeks there has been a flurry of releases from Treasury to give broader effect to the implementation of the Government’s broader reform agenda to improve the sustainability and equity of the superannuation system.

As at 30 September, 2016 there had been two tranches of draft legislation released which provided further detail on how the new rules will operate from 1 July, 2017 and beyond.

At this point, the relevant legislation still needs to pass through Parliament and receive Royal Assent in the normal manner for it to become effective law.

The key elements of the new draft legislation and some of the resulting strategic aspects advisers need to be aware of are outlined below.

What’s new

The key areas addressed in these twin legislative releases will mean that from 1 July, 2017:

  1. The “objective of superannuation” has been established;
  2. A higher spouse income threshold will apply for calculating the spouse contributions tax offsets;
  3. A Low Income Superannuation Tax Offset (LISTO) will apply;
  4. A “transfer balance” cap of $1.6 million is in effect;
  5. The concessional contributions cap (CCs)reduces to $25,000;
  6. The non-concessional contributions (NCCs) cap reduces  to $100,000 per annum (or $300,000 in any three-year period where the “bring-forward” amount is triggered by those able to avail themselves of it);
  7. There is the ability to “catch up” on concessional contributions (note: applicable from 1 July, 2018);
  8. Consumers will see broader retirement income product choice available as a result of income stream product innovation; and
  9. The anti-detriment provision will be abolished.

The objective of superannuation

For the very first time, the objective of the superannuation system is enshrined in legislation covering a “primary” objective and “subsidiary” objectives.

Primary objective

“To provide income in retirement to substitute or supplement the Age Pension.” This is a more expansive purpose than was originally foreshadowed in the 2016 Budget, which merely outlined that the purpose of superannuation was to “supplement” the Age Pension. This primary objective also re-affirms that the purpose of superannuation as “not to allow for tax minimisation or estate planning”.

Subsidiary objectives:

  1. Facilitate consumption smoothing over the course of an individual’s life;
  2. Manage risks in retirement;
  3. Be invested in the best interests of superannuation fund members;
  4. Alleviate fiscal pressures on Government from the retirement income system; and
  5. Be simple, efficient and provide safeguards.

Changes to spouse contribution tax offsets – higher spouse income threshold

From 1 July, 2017, a resident individual will be entitled to a tax offset up to a maximum of $540 in an income year for contributions made to superannuation for their eligible spouse. A spouse will be eligible where the total of the spouse’s assessable income, reportable fringe benefits amounts, and reportable employer superannuation contributions for the income year is less than $40,000 (currently $13,800).

Reduced contributions tax for low income earners – via a new LISTO

From 1 July, 2017, the LISTO seeks to effectively return the tax paid on concessional contributions by a person’s superannuation fund to a person who is a low income earner. Low income earners are defined as individuals with an adjusted taxable income of $37,000 or less. The maximum amount of LISTO payable is $500 per year.

‘Total balance’ cap of $1.6 million

  • Represents the maximum amount which can be transferred into a tax-free income stream for use in retirement, based on “retirement phase” assets calculated as of 30 June, 2017
  • Will index in $100,000 increments in line with the consumer price index (CPI)
  • The transfer balance (TB) cap will be calculated using a “transfer balance” account (TB account) which is similar in concept to an accounting general ledger. Amounts transferred into “retirement phase” (what we presently know as drawing an income stream) give rise to a credit in the account and transfers out (e.g. commutations) give rise to a debit. The TB cap is breached where an individual’s TB account is greater than their relevant TB cap
  • There will be no ability to retain funds in retirement phase in excess of this amount, nor the ability to make additional NCCs once this $1.6 million total superannuation balance threshold is breached. Strict penalties apply for breaches of the TB cap, especially where these are repeated
  • Instead assets will be required to be transferred back to accumulation phase or withdrawn from the superannuation environment entirely. Where assets are transferred to accumulation phase as of 30 June, 2017, a “cost-base” re-set will alleviate the initial capital gains tax (CGT) impact.
  • Complex calculations will apply to the treatment of reversionary income streams for the purposes of the TB cap, however at this stage, reversionary income streams received will also be counted towards the recipients TB cap. Whether this outcome is changed in the final legislation remains to be seen
  • Superannuation balances in excess of the TB cap can remain in accumulation phase indefinitely (and with no balance limit) where they will be taxed at a maximum of 15 per cent
  • Fluctuations in account balances will not be taken into account when determining the available TB cap “space”. For example, where an individual’s account was valued at $1.6 million as of 1 July, 2017, and the balance subsequently declined to $1.4 million on 1 September 2017, they will not be able to add more money into an income stream (called a “retirement phase account”) as they have already fully used their available cap
  • Where an individual only uses part of their TB cap, a “proportionate” approach will apply to assessing eligibility to make further contributions. For example, where an individual transfers $800,000 into a retirement phase account as of 1 July, 2017, they will have used 50 per cent of their available cap. Where the cap is later indexed to $1.8 million they will have 50 per cent of that cap left to use. That is, they will be able to transfer an additional amount of $900,000 into a retirement phase account
  • Personal injury payments contributed within the 90-day window will be exempt from the TB cap
  • Defined benefit schemes will also be subject to the TB cap, with complex calculations required as a result (especially in cases where an individual receives income streams from both taxed and untaxed sources)
  • Modifications to the harsh TB cap are available in cases of a minor child dependant receiving their deceased parent’s benefit
  • New estate planning considerations will arise as a result of the TB cap, which may require review and revision of a client’s estate planning strategy
  • Will also apply to annuities used for retirement purpose. Currently annuities used for retirement purposes are treated very differently to essentially similar monies formally within the superannuation system
  • Importantly, each member of a couple can have a total superannuation balance as of 1 July, 2017 of $1.6 million. There will not be a “shared” $3.2 million cap. That is, there will be zero ability for, say, one party to hold $1 million and the other $2.2 million as of 1 July, 2017 in an attempt to circumvent the new rules

Concessional contributions (CCs) cap changes

  • From 1 July, 2017 the annual cap for each financial year will be $25,000 – currently the cap is $30,000/35,000 per annum
  • The cap will increase in increments of $2,500 in line with average weekly ordinary time earnings (AWOTE) – currently the $30,000 cap is indexed to AWOTE in $5,000 increments
  • Division 293 tax (an extra 15 per cent contributions tax) will apply to an income threshold of $250,000 per annum – currently the threshold is $300,000
  • Special new rules will apply to ensure that contributions to constitutionally protected funds (CPFs) and untaxed or unfunded defined benefits count towards the CCs cap. Currently contributions to CPFs do not count towards the CCs cap, and calculating the impact of relevant contributions for those in untaxed or unfunded defined benefit interests can mean that these remain outside of the CCs cap

New annual NCC cap/revised ‘bring-forward’ rule

  • Can make NCCs of $100,000 a year from 1 July, 2017, or even $300,000 under the revised “bring-forward” rule, so long as an individual is aged under 65 and their total superannuation balances (at 30 June, 2017) is under $1.6 million
  • Where total balances exceed $1.6 million, no NCCs will be permitted. CCs can still be made, in the relevant way
  • Where a balance is “close to” $1.6 million, an individual can only use the “bring-forward” rule to the extent that their super balance stays below $1.6 million
  • Where an individual has partially used the present NCC “bring-forward” rules allowing a $540,000 NCC, they will not be able to benefit from this from 1 July, 2017. Instead, any use of the ‘bring-forward’ rule from 1 July, 2017 will be based on the new caps applying from that date
  • The annual NCC cap and $1.6 million eligibility threshold will be indexed
  • These revised rules will broadly apply to defined benefit and constitutionally protected schemes

‘Catch up’ concessional contributions

  • This increased flexibility benefits those with varying capacity to save and those with interrupted work patterns, to allow them to provide for their own retirement and benefit from the tax concessions to the same extent as those with regular income
  • Individuals aged 65 to 74 who meet the work test will also be able to avail themselves of this proposal
  • Any amounts contributed in excess of the cap will be taxed at the individual’s marginal tax rate, less a 15 per cent tax offset
  • From 1 July, 2018, individuals can “catch-up” on their CCs where their total superannuation balance was less than $500,000 as of 30 June in the previous financial year. Thus, in effect, the first year that an individual will be able to avail themselves of this new measure is 1 July, 2019
  • This measure will mean that additional CCs can be made by using previously unutilised CCs cap amounts from the previous five years
  • Unused cap amounts can be carried forward, with unused CCs cap amounts not used after five years lost

Income stream product innovation

  • In a major step forward for consumer retirement product choice, the earnings tax exemption will now extend to new lifetime products to be known as “deferred products” and “group self-annuities”. Further annuities issued by life companies that represent superannuation income streams will also receive the earnings tax exemption
  • Further, and as previously highlighted, the earnings tax exemption for transition-to-retirement (TTR) income streams will cease from 1 July, 2017. However, TTR income streams will not count for the purposes of the TB cap unless they are considered to be a “standard” account based pension

Farewell to the anti-detriment provision

  • From 1 July, 2017 the anti-detriment (AD) benefit will cease to exist. This benefit effectively provided an uplift to any death benefit paid to that deceased member’s spouse, former spouse and children in the form of a return of contributions tax the deceased member paid during their lifetime
  • For members who die on or after 1 July, 2017, their loved ones will be unable to receive the benefit. For members who pass away before this date and who were within a fund which paid the AD benefit, so long as the AD benefit is paid by 1 July, 2019, their loved ones can still receive it.

Whether the collective outcome of these measures achieve their stated policy aim of improving the sustainability of the $2.1 trillion Australian sector remains to be seen. It is certainly exciting times to be an advice practitioner helping to guide clients through an ever more-complex maze to achieve their desired retirement lifestyle goals.

Catherine Chivers is the manager for strategic advice at Perpetual Private.

Coalition’s super proposals and Labor’s policies – Update November 2016

The Coalition Government’s super proposals

Government’s second tranche super proposals:

On 27 September 2016 the Coalition Government released for public consultation the second tranche of exposure draft legislation and explanatory material to implement a number of the superannuation changes announced in Budget 2016.

Details of the Government’s second tranche is available here. Further information can be found on the Treasury website.

For public submissions on the second tranche, the Government allowed from 27 September 2016 to 10 October 2016; 13 days to consider 234 pages, 57,600 words of very complex, far-reaching proposed legislation.

O’Brien’s, Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s second tranche joint submission to Treasury:

On 10 October 2016, Terrence O’Brien and Jack Hammond QC, on behalf of themselves and Save Our Super lodged with Treasury their joint submission in response to the second tranche. That joint submission is available here.

Tax Institute’s second tranche submission to Treasury:

On 10 October 2016 the Tax Institute lodged its corresponding submission to Treasury. It is available here. It is also publicly available on http://www.taxinstitute.com.au/leadership/advocacy/read-submissions.

In Save Our Super’s opinion, the above submissions demonstrate that the Coalition’s proposed superannuation changes are wrong in principle and unworkable in practice.

Government’s third tranche super proposals:

On 14 October 2016 the Government released for public consultation the third tranche. Details of the Government’s third tranche are available here. The Exposure Draft Bill and Explanatory Material are available on the Treasury website. Public submissions closed on Sunday 23 October 2016; 9 days later.

O’Brien’s, Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s third tranche joint submission to Treasury:

On 23 October 2016, Terrence O’Brien and Jack Hammond QC, on behalf of themselves and Save Our Super lodged with Treasury their joint submission in response to the third tranche. That joint submission is available here.

The limited time allowed for submissions in response to the second and third tranches, makes a mockery of the concept of public consultation. Obviously, the Government wants to rush the superannuation changes through Parliament as soon as possible.

Second and third tranche submissions sent to Coalition

On 10 October 2016 and 24 October 2016 respectively, we wrote to Messrs Gee MP and Buchholz MP in their roles as leaders of the Coalition Backbench Committee on Economics and Finance and sent them copies of:

  1. Terrence O’Brien’s, Jack Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s joint second tranche submission and the Tax Institute’s second tranche submission: and
  2. Terrence O’Brien’s, Jack Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s joint third tranche submission.

Subsequently, we wrote to all Coalition Senators and Coalition MHRs and sent them copies of those submissions.

Labor’s super policies
On 26 June 2016, Labor dropped their 2016 election superannuation policies.  Subsequently, they proposed increased superannuation taxes, despite saying in their policy released just over a year previously, that “If elected, these are the final and only changes Labor will make to the tax treatment of superannuation”. Labor has not announced any replacement superannuation policies.

Save Our Super’s position:

Save Our Super believes that all Parliamentarians should promote and support superannuation policies and legislation which contain grandfathering provisions that maintain the previous entitlements of those Australians who will be significantly affected by major rule changes to the then existing superannuation provisions.

We are convinced that, if the proposed legislation is passed by the House of Representatives, the Senate should subject it to careful scrutiny. It should refer the whole of the Government’s proposed superannuation package to a Senate Committee. The Senate Committee should invite and consider public submissions and objections. The Government’s and Treasury’s assumptions which underpin the changes should be open to public challenge.  On any view, the recently released details of the measures deserve far more detailed scrutiny than has been possible to date in the unreasonably short time made available for consultation.  Moreover, the fragmentation of the measures into tranches of drafting has prevented any integrated overview of how the measures fit together.

UPDATED PETITION

The Federal Coalition Government has made a number of changes to its Budget 2016 superannuation proposals. Consequently, Save Our Super has updated its earlier email petition/s to take into account those changes.

Thank you if you signed the earlier petition/s. Please support, or continue to support, Save Our Super by completing our updated petition here.

 

Submission on third tranche of superannuation exposure drafts

23 October 2016

SUMBISSION ON THIRD TRANCHE OF SUPERANNUATION EXPOSURE DRAFTS

Terrence O’Brien and Jack Hammond QC,

on behalf of themselves and Save Our Super

 

  1. Table of Contents
  2. Summary. 2
  3. Inadequate time for public comment 4
  4. Inappropriate separation of legislative packages. 4
  5. No statement relating tranche measures to objective(s) for superannuation. 4
  6. Why have annual non-concessional contribution limits?. 5
  7. If annual contribution limits continue, why lower them?. 7
  8. A significant contribution to growing complexity. 8
  9. Retrospectivity and effective retrospectivity in the new measures. 8
  10. If lowering annual contribution caps, grandfather for those close to retirement 10
  11. A better path forward. 13

Declaration of interests:

Terrence O’Brien is a retired public servant receiving a super pension from a defined benefit, ‘untaxed’ fund. He would be adversely affected by some of the measures in the second tranche.

Jack Hammond QC is in the process of retiring from his barrister’s practice. He would be adversely affected by some of the measures in the second tranche.

2.    Summary

There are much better ways than the three tranches of measures released so far to improve the lifetime welfare and savings of lower income earners, improve retirement living standards, and improve budget outcomes. The Government should go back to the drawing board on its Budget measures.

If the proposed legislation is passed by the House of Representatives, the Senate should subject it to careful scrutiny. It should refer the whole of the Government’s proposed superannuation package to a Senate Committee. The Senate Committee should invite and consider public submissions and objections. The Government’s and Treasury’s assumptions which underpin the changes should be open to public challenge.

On any view, the recently released details of the measures deserve far more detailed scrutiny than has been possible to date in the unreasonably short time made available for consultation.  Moreover, the fragmentation of the measures into tranches of drafting has prevented any integrated overview of how the measures fit together.

The third tranche Bill proposes reducing the annual concessional (ie before tax) contribution limit by 17% to $25,000 (or by 29% for those over age 50), and the annual non-concessional (ie after tax) contribution limit by 44% to $100,000.

The existing annual contribution limits were created to limit the accumulation of large super balances and have largely achieved that purpose. The number of current large super balances is small as a proportion of total super account balances: 0.5% have over $2.5 million, with most of these balances lawfully accumulated before the implementation of existing law. Those bygones are bygones, and are not a reason for further tightening restrictions on future contribution limits.

If the Government proceeds with its proposed $1.6 million general transfer balance cap (criticised in our submission on tranche two measures), that cap would make the annual non-concessional contribution cap redundant and it could be removed. Instead, the proposed reductions in contribution caps increase the obstacles to current workers ever reaching the Government’s $1.6 million cap (or any other target of their choosing), and reduce welfare by restricting savers’ flexibility to accumulate super savings as their circumstances permit.

For example, for a worker in mid-career with about $340,000 in super (the ‘sweet spot’ that maximizes the combined retirement income from a super pension and a part age pension), the proposed reduction in the non-concessional contribution limits increases the time taken to save up to the super balance cap of $1.6 million by almost 90%, to 13 years, compared to 7 years under the existing contributions cap.[i]

Consider also the living standards offered by a super balance of $1.6 million held by one person of a couple retiring today at age 65. They can expect an indexed annual retirement income of some $72,700 (from age 65 supplemented with part pension from age 82 until death or age 100, assuming an optimistic 5% nominal return net of fees and 3% inflation).[ii] This is about 90% of average weekly earnings. To retire on 90% AWE hardly seems an indecent aspiration, especially if it motivates those who are hard-working, affluent enough and thrifty enough to save hard and forgo easier options to rely on a part age pension.

To combine the general transfer balance cap with lowered annual contribution caps clearly doubles the strength of the message to savers seeking to meet their own preferred standards of retirement income. That message is: “Don’t bother”. The Government has for the first time directly prescribed what it considers a super balance sufficient for retirement ($1.6 million), and has tightened contribution restrictions to hinder reaching even that benchmark.

If alternatively, the Government did not continue with its proposed general transfer balance cap, some case for annual contribution caps would remain. If in that case the Government still wanted to lower them, it should grandfather the reductions for those close to retirement who have planned on the basis of the existing caps and have insufficient time to utilise alternative strategies. The principles for such grandfathering were established by the Asprey inquiry and have been used successfully for forty years. Continuing to utilize them would help contain the damage to trust in super and in super law-making processes.

3.     Inadequate time for public comment

Many of the issues in this third tranche of material have already arisen in first and second tranches, so comments on those issues are abbreviated in this submission.   Paragraph references below are to the Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials for tranche three unless otherwise noted.

Providing only 5 working days for public input on the third tranche of complex super measures shows contempt for public consultation. These are measures that deal with Australians’ life savings, and the realisation of their plans for independent retirement. The measures extensively revise the most complicated aspects of the income tax law affecting individuals, and inject considerable new complexity.

See earlier submissions for comparisons to better consultation processes used in the past.

4.    Inappropriate separation of legislative packages

The compartmentalization across three tranches of draft material for comment has compounded the inadequacies of consultation and has made it difficult to identify connections and interactions among concepts. This submission seeks to touch briefly on some of those cross-cutting issues in the limits of the time available. But the compartmentalized and rushed consultation greatly increases the risk of unintended consequences and the likely need for future unsettling legislative change to repair errors.

5.    No statement relating tranche measures to objective(s) for superannuation

Like the two previous tranches, the third tranche draft bill lacks any statement of rationale against the Government’s stated primary objective (“.. . to provide income in retirement that substitute or supplements the age pension”[iii] ) plus five subordinate objectives.

Our earlier submissions have argued that the Superannuation (Objective) Bill’s proposed objectives for Government policies toward superannuation are unworkable and inappropriate. Yet that proposition can be tested by applying the objectives to the current draft Bill in a statement such as will be mandatory from 1 July 2017.

We are now told that “The final Explanatory Memorandum that will accompany the Bill will provide the overarching policy context.”[iv]  The lack to date of any stated policy context, four months after the announcement of the measures (and their reversal of the Government’s pre-Budget super policy positions) makes considered consultation needlessly difficult. Indeed, the whole process is like starting a construction at the top floors, and finishing up with the foundations.

The documentation asserts (para 3.3) that “The measure will improve the sustainability and integrity of the superannuation system.” No evidence is offered for either of those claims, and as our submission on tranche two measures argues, there is no sense in speaking of ‘sustainability’ in the structure of the super tax concessions: as super balances grow, the Governments tax take from contributions and accumulation grows, and the considered, well-researched and well-costed strategic decision of 2005-06 not to collect tax on most retirement income streams remains unchanged. The focus of taxation of growing commitments to life-long savings in superannuation on the contribution and accumulation phases is no more ‘unsustainable’ than the identical focus of taxation on growing sums in savings accounts, which are also untaxed in their drawdown phase.

6.    Why have annual non-concessional contribution limits?

Concessional and non-concessional contribution limits were introduced to limit the accumulation of large super balances, and seem to be largely succeeding in that objective.

The explanatory material rationalises this objective oddly: “To ensure superannuation is being used for its primary purpose of saving for retirement, and not for tax minimisation, there are limits on the amount of non-concessional contributions individuals can make.” (para 3.4)

As noted in our earlier submissions, special tax treatment of super since 1915 is not a gift to super funds or savers: it exists to remove the significant disincentive to long term saving from the interaction of a progressive tax on nominal income with the provision of a generous age pension. It makes no sense to accuse citizens who lawfully follow incentives to save in super of ‘tax minimisation’ beyond some arbitrary (but apparently ever-evolving) point. In April 2016, the current contribution limits were apparently appropriately scaled to defend thrift against discouragement by income tax and the age pension. In May 2016, citizens lawfully fully utilizing those legislated limits were apparently guilty of ‘tax minimisation’. What changed?

All saving in super is in one sense ‘tax minimisation’ – that is how the incentives achieve their intended effect. Branding savers who follow lawful incentives ‘tax minimisers’ in an attempt to rationalize an otherwise unexplained tax increase does not seem a helpful guide to policy development, but rather adds to the destruction of trust in super. It reminds all super savers that today’s lawful thrift transparently encouraged by government incentives enacted through Parliament is open to excoriation as tomorrow’s ‘tax minimisation’.

While anecdotes of very large super balances still circulate, there are relatively few such balances and most of the current high balances were accumulated under previous rules (or in the absence of rules). A 2015 report by Ross Clare for the Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia suggested that there is a small proportion (around 0.5 per cent) of super savers who have very high account superannuation balances (above $2.5 million). Most large balances existing today owe their existence to former incentives that, in times past, were unbounded or much less restricted than at present.[v]

In super taxation policy, the homely adage that ‘bygones are bygones’ is particularly important. Superannuation has a uniquely long lifespan, with current retirees living off savings which began to be lawfully accumulated as long ago as the middle of the last century. Policy design for super tomorrow requires the comparison of future marginal costs and future marginal benefits of alternatives open to choice today.

It is a significant misdirection to tomorrow’s super policy to point to relatively few large super balances built on decades of savings under the less restrictive laws of the past as justification for additional restriction in future laws, when current laws already heavily restrict any future accumulation of high balances.

If the Government proceeds with the proposed $1.6 m general transfer balance account cap, it is not clear why any non-concessional contribution limits would be necessary going forward; their role today would in future be taken by the cap. These comments focus, as does the draft Bill, on the non-concessional contribution cap which bear the brunt of the Government’s new restrictions, being cut by 2 ½ times the percentage cut in concessional contribution cap. This is notwithstanding the fact that against the pre-paid consumption tax which is the most defensible benchmark for neutral treatment of long term savings, non-concessional contributions are (as their name rightly suggests) no concession at all. Indeed, against that benchmark, users of a non-concessional contribution, having paid tax at their top marginal tax on their contribution, are still over-taxed by the 15% tax on subsequent earnings within the fund.[vi]

Continuing with any annual non-concessional contribution limits merely restricts the flexibility with which individuals can adapt to their personal circumstances and maximise their super savings when they are able to, up to the limit of the cap.  For example, a small business owner may envisage retiring and rolling the proceeds from selling their business into a super fund. Or another individual may receive a bequest. To reduce the rate at which they can save towards the cap would seem to serve no revenue purpose, but would reduce their welfare and potentially the total that could be saved in super. Alternative tax-efficient forms of long-term saving such as negatively-geared real estate or the principal residence would likely produce a less productive allocation of scarce capital from an economy-wide perspective.

If, nevertheless, the Government were to seek revenue from past balances lawfully saved by taxing them more heavily, there should be a very clear understanding of the effective retrospectivity of that course, with all of the costs to trust in super, legitimacy and future savings. Such retrospective measures should not be misrepresented as responding to a prospective problem.

7.    If annual contribution limits continue, why lower them?

The measures propose a 44 % cut in the annual non-concessional contribution cap, and a 17% cut in the concessional contribution cap (or by 29% for those over age 50). Yet the explanatory materials claim:

By reducing the non‑concessional annual caps and restricting their use to those with balances less than the transfer balance cap, this measure will better target the tax concessions to encourage those who have aspirations to build their superannuation balance up to the limit of the transfer balance cap while retaining the flexibility to accommodate lump sum contributions from one-off events such as receiving an inheritance or selling a large asset. (para 3.4)

Contrary to this unsubstantiated claim, lowering the contributions limits sends the opposite message — discouragement — compared to simply leaving the existing limits in place. Consider the case of a super saver in Tony Negline’s ‘sweet spot’: about $340,000 in super, the amount that maximizes the combined retirement income from a super pension and a part age pension.[vii] To move from that super balance to $1.6 million by non-concessional contributions would take almost 90% longer, 13 years after the proposed cut, compared to 7 year under the existing cap.

That is a powerful message:  not only is the Government for the first time prescribing a maximum to the most tax-assisted saving limit to force reallocation of lawful savings by those who have already saved a lot; it is simultaneously prescribing lowered limits in annual saving rates for those in their late-career savings phase that will prevent many not already at the cap from ever reaching it.

The combined message from tranche two and tranche three measures is that the optimum saving strategy is $340k or so in super, a part age pension, a valuable house and many other options to keep savings outside the pension asset test.

The upshot of this and the other two tranches’ measures is likely to be to increase total Government retirement income costs over time, while crimping the rise in Australians’ retirement living standards – failures of policy that apparently have not been detected within the government’s asserted analytical framework of one principal objective plus five subordinate objectives for super policy.

As SMSF adviser Daryl Dixon has noted:

There’s about 2000 people with a hell of a lot of money in super. Right?

There are at least 20 to 30 thousand with a lot of money in an owner–occupied house worth 5 to 10 million or more, and there’s no capital gains and there’s no tax on the profits of the house.[viii]

8.    A significant contribution to growing complexity

By far the greatest source of complexity in the superannuation measures is the introduction of the new structure of ‘transfer balance accounts’, ‘general transfer balance caps’, ‘personal transfer balance caps’ and ‘excess transfer balance’ taxes, as detailed in our submission on the second tranche measures.

While the concepts of concessional and non-concessional contribution limits are at least familiar to savers from the present law, lowering them as proposed adds to complexity through the need to plot their interaction with the new transfer balance cap apparatus. The Explanatory Materials take some 9 pages to explain the interaction of the contribution limits with the transfer cap (pages 9 to 18).

9.    Retrospectivity and effective retrospectivity in the new measures

Under present law, an individual can make $540,000 of non-concessional contributions by bringing forward 3 years’ of the current non-concessional contribution cap of $180,000. Various media commentary has advised super savers to make use of this provision before new laws take effect (if passed by Parliament) on 1 July 2017.[ix]

However it seems from the ‘transitional provisions’ of the Bill discussed at paras 3.57 to 3.66 of the draft explanatory materials that the new Bill, if passed by Parliament, would retrospectively (in the narrowest sense of the term) penalize that bring-forward, by allowing a $180,000 contribution for 2016-17, but allowing only a reduced $100,000 for each of 2017-18 and 2018-19 (assuming no indexation by the CPI of the contribution caps by 2018-19).

Precisely how the saver will be retrospectively penalized after 1 July 2017 for a lawful bring forward of non-concessional contributions made before 1 July 2017 is not clear in the time made available for consultation and with the draft explanatory material. Para 3.44 flags another area where treatment of defined benefit schemes has not yet been resolved by advisers. However, paras 3.41 to 3.43, and new material governing how the Commissioner for Taxation must (or may) respond to ‘excess’ contributions through the issue of release authorities (13 pages of material from para 10.1 to 10.68) contain illustrations of the assessment of penalty taxes under Division 293. Once again, the extraction of penalties in such a situation is a retrospective change of law in the narrowest sense.

Beyond this issue of narrow retrospectivity, there is the broader issue of ‘effective retrospectivity’ as defined by Treasurer Morrison in his address of 18 February 2016.[x] A generation of savers (those aged around 40 to 60) now enjoying peak career earnings and planning lifetime peak contributions to their super balances in the lead up to retirement would have their savings plans destroyed by the radical cuts to contribution caps (and especially the 44% cut to non-concessional contributions caps).

Many of those late career savers are too close to retirement to be able to devise alternative strategies for self-funded retirement, and will likely choose a path of more reliance on a part age pension and the construction of wealth in avenues not penalized by the age pension means test. To limit the destruction in trust in super among that savings group, the Government should grandfather its measures along the principles outlined by Justice Asprey and used over the last 40 years in other tax increases on superannuation. Application of those principles is further references below.

10. If lowering annual contribution caps, grandfather for those close to retirement

The challenges of facilitating gradual increases in super taxes while not destroying confidence in super were addressed most thoughtfully by the late Justice Kenneth Asprey, who was commissioned by the outgoing McMahon Government to report on the Australian taxation system. Asprey made his Committee’s final report to the Whitlam Government. His recommendations at first had little apparent effect, but it they drove all the major advances in Australian tax reform over the following quarter century:

The capital gains tax, the fringe benefits tax, dividend imputation, the foreign tax credit system, the goods and services tax (he called it a “broad-based value-added tax”) — all were proposed in the Asprey report.[xi]

The Asprey insights into the need to grandfather super tax increases, and his principles for how to do that while preserving necessary policy flexibility to respond to changing circumstances, are summarised in the following Box.

More recently, the Gillard Government’s Superannuation Charter Group led by Jeremy Cooper addressed concerns about the future of the super savings and the way policy changes have been made.[xii] The Charter Group reported to the second Rudd Government in July 2013 with useful proposals in the nature of a ‘superannuation constitution’ that would codify the nature of the compact between governments and savers, including:

  • People should have sufficient confidence in the regulatory settings and their evolution to trust their savings to superannuation, including making voluntary contributions.
  • Relevant considerations, when assessing policy against the principle of certainty, include the ability for people to plan for retirement and adjust to superannuation policy changes with confidence.
  • “People should have sufficient time to alter their arrangements in response to proposed policy changes. This issue becomes more acute for those nearing or in retirement, who have fewer options and less time available to them (for example, to increase contributions or remain in the workforce longer).” [xiii] (emphahsis added)

Box: Grandfathering principles: Asprey Taxation Review, Chapter 21, 1975

Principle 1    21.9. Finally, and most importantly, it must be borne in mind that the matters with which the Committee is here dealing involve long-term commitments entered into by taxpayers on the basis of the existing taxation structure. It would be unfair to such persons if a significantly different taxation structure were to be introduced without adequate and reasonable transitional arrangements. ………

Principle 2    21.61. …..Many people, particularly those nearing retirement, have made their plans for the future on the assumption that the amounts they receive on retirement would continue to be taxed on the present basis. The legitimate expectations of such people deserve the utmost consideration. To change suddenly to a harsher basis of taxing such receipts would generate justifiable complaints that the legislation was retrospective in nature, since the amounts concerned would normally have accrued over a considerable period—possibly over the entire working life of the person concerned. …..

Principle 3    21.64. There is nonetheless a limit to the extent to which concern over such retrospectivity can be allowed to influence recommendations for a fundamental change in the tax structure. Pushed to its extreme such an argument leads to a legislative straitjacket where it is impossible to make changes to any revenue law for fear of disadvantaging those who have made their plans on the basis of the existing legislation.   …..

Principle 4    21.81. …. [I]t is necessary to distinguish legitimate expectations from mere hopes. A person who is one day from retirement obviously has a legitimate expectation that his retiring allowance or superannuation benefit which may have accrued over forty years or more will be accorded the present treatment. On the other hand, it is unrealistic and unnecessary to give much weight to the expectations of the twenty-year-old as to the tax treatment of his ultimate retirement benefits.

Principle 5    21.82. In theory the approach might be that only amounts which can be regarded as accruing after the date of the legislation should be subject to the new treatment. This would prevent radically different treatment of the man who retires one day after that date and the man who retires one day before. It would also largely remove any complaints about retroactivity in the new legislation ….

These Charter Group suggestions would also appear to support the use of grandfathering in the case of the Government’s proposed restriction on non-concessional contributions.

Since at least 1994, concessional contributions caps have specifically recognized that capacity to save rose later in workers’ careers, so caps for those over 50 were substantially higher than for those under 35.[xiv] For an over-50 in 1994, the annual concessional contribution limit was $62,200, and had been indexed to over $105,000 by the time of its abolition under the Costello simplification reforms of 2006. These earlier high caps of course help explain why some very high super balances still exist today.

Treasurer Swan’s 2009-10 Budget lowered the annual concessional contributions cap from $50,000 to $25,000 for those under 50. But for those aged 50 and over for the 2009-10, 2010-11 and 2011-12 financial years, the cap was lowered from $100,000 to $50,000 per annum.

The 2009-2010 Budget papers noted:

‘Grandfathering’ arrangements were applied to certain members with defined benefit interests as at 12 May 2009 whose notional taxed contributions would otherwise exceed the reduced cap. Similar arrangements were applied when the concessional contributions cap was first introduced. [xv]

Similarly, regulatory changes that affected savers’ planning for retirement late in their working careers were phased in to spare those closest to retirement and to give advance notice to those further from retirement to make adjustments to their financial affairs. An example was the 1997-1998 Budget confirmation of phased increases in the preservation age from 55 to 60 by 2025..[xvi]

A further illustration of recent relevance from the intersection of superannuation and the aged pension is the grandfathering of existing account-based superannuation pensions outside the aged pension income test, rather than deeming them as income counted against the test from 1 January 2015 as part of the revisions to that test.[xvii]

Further details showing how grandfathering adverse changes to superannuation and related retirement income parameters has been used over the last 40 years are contained in Terrence O’Brien’s paper for the Centre for Independent Studies, Grandfathering super tax increases.[xviii]

11. A better path forward

There are much better ways than the three tranches of measures released so far to improve the lifetime welfare and savings of lower income earners, such as illustrated in papers for the CIS by Simon Cowan and Michael Potter[xix]. A sensible selection from and development of those ideas would improve self-sufficiency and thrift, improve superannuation outcomes, improve retirement living standards, and improve budget outcomes. The Government should go back to the drawing board on its Budget measures.

If the proposed legislation is passed by the House of Representatives, the Senate should subject it to careful scrutiny. It should refer the whole of the Government’s proposed superannuation package to a Senate Committee. The Senate Committee should invite and consider public submissions and objections. The Government’s and Treasury’s assumptions which underpin the changes should be open to public challenge.

On any view, the recently released details of the measures deserve far more detailed scrutiny than has been possible to date in the unreasonably short time made available for consultation.  Moreover, the fragmentation of the measures into tranches of drafting has prevented any integrated overview of how the measures fit together.

[i] Tony Negline, Saving or slaving: find the sweet spot for super, The Australian, 4 October 2016.

[ii] Trish Power, Crunching the numbers: a $1.6 million retirement, SuperGuide, 23 May 2016.

[iii] Scott Morrison and Kelly O’Dwyer, Superannuation reforms: first tranche of Exposure Drafts , 7 September 2016

[iv] The Treasury, Superannuation reform package – tranche three, online Consultation Hub, accessed 21 October 2016.

[v] Ross Clare, Superannuation and high account balances, Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia, April 2015.

[vi] Ken Henry et al, Australia’s Future Tax System: Report to the Treasurer, Part Two; Detailed analysis, Volume 1, Box A2-1p 97

[vii] Tony Negline, Saving or slaving: find the sweet spot for super, The Australian, 4 October 2016.

[viii] Daryl Dixon and Nerida Cole on Nightlife with Tony Delroy, ABC, 12 July 2016.

Election over: now they want to take more of your Super and Labor may allow it

[ix] See, for one example, Will Hamillton of Hamilton Wealth Management, Six most common questions on superannuation, The Australian, 1 October 2016.

[x] Scott Morrison, Address to the SMSF 2016 National Conference, Adelaide, 18 February 2016

[xi] Ross Gittins, A light on the hill for our future tax reformers, The Age 15 June 2009.

[xii] Jeremy Cooper, A Super Charter: Fewer Changes, Better Outcomes: A report to the Treasurer and Minister Assisting for Financial Services and Superannuation, Canberra, 5 July 2013.

[xiii] ibid, p 47

[xiv] AMP, Submission on Concessional Contributions Caps for Individuals Aged 50 and Over, March 2011.

[xv] Australian Government, Budget 2009-10, Budget Paper No 2, part 1, Revenue Measures, Canberra 12 May 2009.

[xvi] Trish Power, Accessing super: Preservation age now 56 years (since July 2015),

MLC Super Guide, 5 July 2015.

[xvii] Liam Shorte, Age pension changes: keeping your super grandfathered, Intelligent Investor, 26 August 2014.

[xviii] Terrence O’Brien, Grandfathering super tax increases, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy, Vol. 32 No. 3 (Spring, 2016), pp3-12.

[xix] Michael Potter, Don’t increase the super guarantee, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy, Vol. 32 No. 3 (Spring, 2016), pp27-36,

Budget 2016 Proposals and Opposition’s Policies – Update 18 October 2016

Government’s second and third tranches of proposed superannuation changes

UPDATE:

On 27 September 2016 the Government released for public consultation the second tranche of exposure draft legislation and explanatory material to implement a number of the superannuation changes announced in the 2016-17 Budget.

Details of the Government’s second tranche is available here. Further information can be found on the Treasury website.

On 14 October 2016 the Government released the third tranche. Details of the Government’s third tranche are available here. The Exposure Draft Bill and Explanatory Memorandum are available on the Treasury website. Submissions will close on Friday 21 October 2016.

Government’s second tranche:

For Public Submissions on the second tranche, the Government allowed from 27 September 2016 to 10 October 2016; 13 days to consider 234 pages, 57,600 words of very complex, far-reaching proposed legislation. That makes a mockery of the concept of public consultation. Obviously, the Government wants to rush it through Parliament as soon as possible.

O’Brien’s Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s second tranche joint submission to Treasury:

Save Our Super has considered the second tranche of the Government’s superannuation changes. On 10 October 2016, Terrence O’Brien and Jack Hammond QC, on behalf of themselves and Save Our Super lodged with Treasury their joint submission in response to the second tranche. That joint submission is available here.

Tax Institute’s second tranche submission to Treasury:

On 10 October 2016 the Tax Institute lodged its corresponding submission to Treasury. It is available here. It is also publicly available on http://www.taxinstitute.com.au/leadership/advocacy/read-submissions.

Today we wrote to Messrs Gee MP and Buchholz MP in their roles as leaders of the Coalition Backbench Committee on Economics and Finance to convey a copy of Terrence O’Brien’s, Jack Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s joint submission and the Tax Institute’s submission, both lodged 10 October 2016 with Treasury on the second tranche of Government superannuation measures.

We also wrote today to all Coalition Senators and Coalition MHRs and sent them copies of those submissions.

Those two independently and separately compiled submissions complement each other. In our opinion, the first demonstrates that the Government’s second tranche proposed superannuation changes are wrong in principle; the second that they will be unworkable in practice.

We are convinced that, if the proposed legislation is passed by the House of Representatives, the Senate should subject it to careful scrutiny. It should refer the whole of the Government’s proposed superannuation package to a Senate Committee. The Senate Committee should invite and consider public submissions and objections. The Government’s and Treasury’s assumptions which underpin the changes should be open to public challenge.  On any view, the recently released details of the measures deserve far more detailed scrutiny than has been possible to date in the unreasonably short time made available for consultation.  Moreover, the fragmentation of the measures into tranches of drafting has prevented any integrated overview of how the measures fit together.

Save Our Super believes that grandfather clauses must be provided to protect all significantly affected Australians from a number of the remaining Budget 2016 superannuation proposals.

Support our joint submission:

Tell your Coalition Senators and Coalition Members of the House of Representatives that you support Terrence O’Brien’s, Jack Hammond QC’s and Save Our Super’s joint submission in response to the second tranche of the Government’s superannuation changes. Your message can be more effective if you also tell your personal story to your local Federal representatives.

Please send an email, write a letter, phone and/or call in and see your Federal Senators and local MP. Please ensure you include your residential address as they will take more notice of their local constituents. We are sure they’d love to see you!

Save Our Super’s Pillars of Principle

“Trust” and “Certainty” are Save Our Super’s “Pillars of Principle”. They are fundamental. Only with those two pillars of principle in place can a fair and sustainable Australian superannuation system survive and flourish.

Trust

First, a government should not undermine people’s trust in the superannuation system.

Trust is shattered when, for example, a Minister like Treasurer Morrison makes, and then shamelessly breaks, his promises regarding the government’s future tax treatment of superannuation.

Certainty

Secondly, a government should not undermine certainty in the superannuation system.

Certainty is lost when, for example, government changes long-standing superannuation rules and policies without notice nor consultation and without the use of appropriate grandfathering provisions.

For example, for over 100 years, since at least 1915, the pension account of superannuation fund earnings has been exempt from taxation. There are sound policy reasons for not taxing people in their pension phase. They are at their most financially vulnerable time, with none, or limited opportunity to increase lost capital or increase their paid worktime. Yet, as a matter of principle, both the Coalition and Labor will tax peoples’ pension phase account earnings.

Moreover, even where people have relied upon existing rules and policies, and those people will be significantly affected by proposed changes, neither the Coalition nor Labor will protect their superannuation savings by the use of appropriate grandfathering provisions.

Only after government has considered and applied those two pillars of principle, should government turn to see which, if any, changes should be made to the superannuation system, and then calculate their taxation effect.

Government should not start with the amount of tax they want to raise or save from superannuants, and then formulate their superannuation policies.

Save Our Super will vigorously advocate that the L/NP Coalition, Labor and other parliamentarians adopt those two pillars of principle in the application of their superannuation policies and legislation.

Save Our Super will not negotiate, horse-trade or bargain away the two fundamental pillars of principle, namely, “Trust” and “Certainty”. Their application is essential for good public policy and precedent.

Tax Institute’s second tranche submission

taxinstitute_log_tagline

10 October 2016

Ms Jenny Wilkinson
Division Head
Retirement Income Policy Division
The Treasury
Langton Crescent
PARKES ACT 2600

Submitted electronically: https://consult.treasury.gov.au/retirement-income-policydivision/super-reform-package-tranche-2/consultation/intro/view

Dear Ms Wilkinson

Superannuation reform package – tranche 2

The Tax Institute welcomes the opportunity to make a submission to the Treasury in relation to the Superannuation reform package – tranche 2 set of exposure drafts and explanatory memoranda (Tranche 2).

Given the short timeframe provided for submissions on Tranche 2, the submission below does not purport to cover all of the substantive issues arising from this material.

The Institute, along with its expert members in the area of superannuation, would be pleased to provide additional details on any of the matters set out below or to address the material in more detail in person.

Summary

The Institute submits that further consultation is required to discuss and resolve the technical challenges in administering the current measures in practice. We strongly urge the Government to consider the practical difficulties with some of these measures and be open to consider alternatives that could largely achieve the same objective, but also with the subsidiary objective that the superannuation system be simple, efficient and provide safeguards in mind.

Discussion

General comments

We submit that the consultation period for the superannuation reform package should be extended to allow a more considered redrafting of the exposure drafts. A consultation period of nine business days has been provided for the public to provide comments on Tranche 2, which comprises approximately 220 pages of exposure drafts and explanatory memoranda. This is an insufficient period to provide considered comments on this significant and complex material, which taxpayers and their advisers will be dealing with for decades to come.

Members of the Institute’s Superannuation Committee also consider a start date of 1 July 2017 for many of the measures in the package is not realistic given the uncertainty around the final form of the legislation and the considerable systems and other work that trustees and administrators need to do to implement the measures.

We understand that some consultation on Tranche 2 has taken place on a confidential basis. The current drafting of the material focusses primarily on administration, procedure and systems. Given the volume of technical issues that have become apparent at the draft legislation stage (many of which are set out in this submission), we are concerned that an appropriate cross-section of stakeholders in the superannuation system have not been consulted at an early stage. We have heard from members whose organisations have been consulted on a confidential basis that they have not been able to gather feedback from other relevant stakeholders and experts within their particular fund or organisation to improve the quality of the legislative package.

While the explanatory memoranda for Tranche 2 predicts further consultation on some discrete issues, this form of ad hoc consultation coupled with the release of the superannuation reform package in tranches increases the risk of interaction issues, consequential amendments and any necessary transitional relief not being fully considered or identified. For example, the interaction between the introduction of the transfer balance cap in Tranche 2 with the amendments contemplated in relation to eligibility for making non-concessional contributions, cannot be considered because the non-concessional contribution amendments have not yet been released. Another example identified is how an excess above transfer caps will work where the super fund invests solely in investment policies with life companies which are taxed exclusively under Division 320.

We are concerned that the exposure drafts are inconsistent with the subsidiary objective of superannuation that the superannuation system be simple, efficient and provide safeguards. In particular, the drafting of Tranche 2 is overly complex and cannot be readily understood without reference to explanatory memoranda, which do not have legal force on a standalone basis. For example, the exposure drafts introduce approximately 23 new definitions into the tax law, with requirements to maintain account of multiple new superannuation concepts – including Transfer Balance Accounts, Personal Transfer Balance Caps, Unused Cap Space, Unused Cap Percentage and Highest Transfer Balance.

Further, we consider the use of accounting terms such as debits and credits in the transfer balance cap to be generally inappropriate in their application to the new superannuation concepts, and they may invite a quasi-accounting construction of the provisions – moving away from well-known legal principles and judicial concepts applied in superannuation and tax law. In addition, the draft material does not appear to adopt the strict accounting definitions and therefore could cause confusion for advisers and risk misinterpretation by superannuants. The uncertainty of announced measures and the substance that will ultimately become law means advisers cannot properly inform clients on these measures at this stage. Other than accountants, not many people are aware that a debit is an entry that affects the left side of an accounting ledger, whilst a credit affects the right side. In the absence of specialist assistance, which forces up compliance costs, the use of such concepts will result in mistakes being be made.

The media release issued by the Hon Scott Morrison MP, the Treasurer, on 27 September 2016 in relation to Tranche 2 states that 96 per cent of individuals with superannuation will either be better off or unaffected as a result of these changes.1 The Institute wishes to point out that the likely substantial administrative costs of implementing these measures will not be limited to those individuals directly impacted by the measures in revenue terms.

Significant education, updating documentation, upskilling process and reporting costs will also be incurred by the industry and that will be incurred all members to implement the systems necessary to comply with these measures. For example, some industry funds have more than 5 million members but the key measures may impact very few within these funds but all of the members of the fund will generally be required to pay for the updated systems to cater for the new changes The complexity of the measures is also likely to lead to further costs and inefficiencies in terms of work created by misunderstandings and errors that requires a fair degree of learning and education to be rolled out to members by fund providers, advisers, ATO and Government. The costs of collection of each $1.00 of revenue from each proposal should be tested to ensure the costs are not out of proportion to the revenue gained. The industry-wide costs should be considered and not just a fund-specific cost.

Given the above issues, the Institute considers that the introduction of the measures to Parliament in sufficiently clear and certain form by the end of the calendar year is ambitious. The application of the majority of the amendments in Tranche 2 to commence on 1 July 2017 also provides insufficient lead time to finalise and implement the measures, particularly given that other tax measures such as the Attribution Managed Investment Trust regime and measures to improve compliance through enhanced third party reporting and data matching will also impact on large superannuation funds and also commence on 1 July 2017. Furthermore, Trustees and Registrable Superannuation Entities are already facing a myriad of regulatory reform measures from both APRA and ASIC (ranging from MySuper ADA transfers to enhanced disclosure/reporting with Regulatory Guide 97 Disclosing fees and costs in PDSs and periodic statements).

Transfer balance cap

Defined benefit funds

The Institute is concerned about the lack of clarity for how credits and debits are to be applied to the transfer balance account for members with multiple income streams across multiple funds where some of those income streams (lifetime pensions) are “non-commutable superannuation income streams” referred to as “capped defined benefit income streams”. Special values are applied to determine the credit to the transfer balance account for members with lifetime pensions or certain other term pensions and then special rules apply to calculating the debit value of the income stream – unlike for other account based income streams where the actual lump sum commutation value is applied as a debit against the transfer balance account (possibly resulting in a negative balance).

As such, the Institute notes that the new rules will, in effect, require separate sub-accounts of the transfer balance account to be maintained in respect of lifetime pensions – because it would appear that a commutation amount (in respect of a lifetime pension or like income stream) cannot be applied as a debit to the transfer balance account without calculating the special debit value by reference to the special value credited to the account when the lifetime pension or like income stream commenced. Paragraph 1.186 of the Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials appears to confirm this:

1.186 The extent to which an excess is attributable to capped defined benefit income streams is worked out by reference to an individual’s capped defined benefit balance. This balance is a sub-account of the individual’s transfer balance account and includes all debits and credits that relate to capped defined benefit income streams. That is, the capped defined benefit balance reflects the net amount of capital an individual has transferred to the retirement phase in respect of capped defined benefit income streams. [Schedule 1, Part 1, item 3, subsection 294-125(3) of the ITAA 1997]

There would appear to be a high likelihood for misunderstandings, misreporting and mistakes to occur in respect of these kinds of blended transfer balance accounts (operating with a sub-account). As a minimum, the Institute considers that the Commissioner should be given broad discretion to issue relief with respect to such matters.

Calculation of the cap (credits)

Credits to the transfer balance cap measure include death benefit/reversionary pensions. While the legislation makes it clear that any amounts over the transfer balance cap must be commuted it is not clear whether death benefits can be commuted into accumulation phase or whether they must be paid as lump sums pursuant to regulation 6.21 of the Superannuation Industry (Supervision) Regulations (SISR). The examples used in the Explanatory Materials for child pensions would suggest that the measures foresee that a cashing out of the excess as a lump sum will be required.

Spouses and other financial dependants have always been permitted to continue to hold their spouse’s death benefits in their superannuation funds by way of a reversionary pension or death benefit pension. The examples used in the Explanatory Materials for child pensions would suggest that the measures foresee that a cashing out of the excess as a lump sum will be required. If funds are no longer permitted to provide pension benefits to reversionary spouses and children under age 25 and other financial dependants for amounts over the transfer balance cap (or adjusted cap in the case of child pensions) that is a significant change from the current rules. Such a position would also go against the rationale of the current measure (i.e. that the measure is not designed to stop members accumulating benefits but rather caps out the pension phase tax concession).

The Institute notes the likelihood of significant liquidity issues arising for some superannuation funds if substantial portions of current reversionary pensions are required to be cashed by 1 July 2017.

We submit that the legislation should be amended to permit death benefits being paid in the form of a pension under SISR (i.e. spouses, financial dependants and interdependents) to be commuted to accumulation phase and to not be required to be cashed out of the superannuation system. This could be in an accumulation account or a taxable pension account. Alternatively, such “excess death benefit pensions” could be retained as pensions but not qualify as exempt current pension income

As a minimum, this measure should be available to in effect grandfather any death benefit/reversionary income streams that have commenced prior to 1 July 2017.

It is also relevant to note in the context of death benefit income streams/reversionary pensions that many superannuation products may have been issued to members (and paid for) as a reversionary income stream product. A requirement to cause excess transfer cap amounts to be cashed out of the superannuation system significantly alters the structure of the product that members may have selected and paid for and the Institute submits this provides further support for allowing these death benefits to be retained in accumulation phase within the superannuation system
In addition to the comments above, we note the phrase “retirement phase recipient of a superannuation income stream” is used a number of times. It is submitted that the phrase “retirement phase recipient” is sufficient (and less circular).

Excess transfer balance determinations and tax

The Institute would submit that the Commissioner be given a broad discretion to remit excess transfer balance tax or disregard a certain period when determining the notional earnings where the delay in issuing a determination is beyond the control of the member. The Institute is particularly concerned that this may likely occur if insufficient lead time to finalise and implement results in delays with Funds reporting and/or ATO to issue determinations within a reasonable time of receiving all the information.

Miscellaneous

The Institute is also concerned about the penal nature of the imposition of a 30% tax on second and subsequent breaches of the cap due to the complexity of the measures and the length of time over which taxpayers are likely to be in receipt of income streams following retirement. There is a high possibility of one or more errors with respect to an individual’s income streams across multiple providers and over periods in excess of 20 or so years. Further, it is noted that there is no equivalent concept for a further sanction to be applied to the capped defined benefit tax.

Catch up concessional contributions

Schedule 6 of the Treasury Laws Amendment (Fair and Sustainable Superannuation) Bill 2016 Exposure Draft contains amendments to the Income Tax Assessment Act 1997 to give effect to the Government’s 2016/17 Federal Budget measure ‘Superannuation Reform Package – Catch-up Concessional Contributions’.

In our view, broadly the proposed changes are positive changes in terms of allowing individuals to make catch-up contributions where they have not fully utilised their concessional contribution caps in the previous five financial years, noting that the measure requires that they have a total superannuation balance of less than $500,000 on 30 June in year prior to making the catch-up contribution. This measure allows those who may not had the capacity or support in previous years to increase their superannuation account balances to a level commensurate with that which they would have enjoyed if the concessional cap had been fully utilised.

However, we note the following issues:

  • The mechanism for allowing the catch-up is confusing.
  • The basis for determining the total superannuation account balance at a particular time appears to contain an error.

Confusing mechanism for applying the catch-up

The draft legislation introduces two related but separate concepts – “unused concessional contributions cap” and “unapplied unused concessional contribution cap”. For each financial year the “unused concessional contribution cap” is to be determined. It is the amount by which concessional contributions fall short of the concessional contributions cap for a particular year. This amount is not adjusted even where catch-up contributions are made in future years. Instead, a second concept of “unapplied unused concessional contribution cap” is introduced.

Rather than reducing the unused concessional contributions cap as it is utilised in making catch-up payments in subsequent years, the legislation requires a separate determination of the unapplied unused concessional contribution cap. As previously unused concessional contributions caps are utilised or applied, the unapplied unused concessional contribution cap reduces, but without reducing the unused concessional contribution cap.
The mechanism is likely to cause confusion given that the unused concessional contribution cap does not reduce as it is applied (or used). It seems a more logical and intuitive approach would be to determine the unused concessional contribution cap initially for a financial year, and then for the legislation to provide for this amount to be reduced as it is applied (or used) so that at any point in time the “unused concessional contribution cap” for a financial year reflected the amount that was otherwise available for the individual to use in making catch up concessional contributions

Total superannuation account balance

In Part 2 of Schedule 6 the draft legislation sets out a mechanism for determining the “total superannuation account balance” at a particular time. This is relevant in determining whether a member has a total superannuation balance less than $500,000 on the last day of the financial year preceding the year in which they wish to make catch-up payments.

The draft legislation breaks down the balance into separate components, and sets out a specific mechanism for determining the retirement phase value of an individual’s total superannuation balance which arises because an individual has a transfer balance account. The explanatory memorandum in paragraph 6.28 described the approach in the following terms: “The retirement phase value of the individual’s total superannuation balance is determined by the balance of their transfer balance account, adjusted to reflect the current value of account based superannuation interests in retirement phase.”

However, the specific mechanism in the proposed legislation appears confusing, unnecessary and potentially incorrect.
Specifically, section 307-230(2)(b) requires one to “increase the amount of (the transfer balance account) balance by the total amount of the superannuation benefits that would become payable if” the individual had a right to cause the superannuation interest to cease and voluntarily caused the interest to so cease. It seems that the word “by” ought to instead be replaced by the word “to” – that is, that the adjustment required is to the amount that the member would have been paid had they voluntarily ceased, rather than increasing it by the total amount they would have received in those circumstances (the latter appears likely to give rise to a double counting and over-inflation of the member’s retirement phase value).
It is also unclear why such a mechanism is to be adopted and whether it achieves the outcome suggested in the explanatory memorandum. As an alternative approach it may be more appropriate that instead of taking the amount of the transfer balance account at the time and then seeking to increase it by an appropriate adjustment, that instead the balance of the account would be taken as the total amount of the superannuation benefit that would become payable if there was a right to cease the interests at the time and the individual voluntarily caused their interest to cease at that time.

Innovative income streams and integrity

New Deferred Superannuation Income Streams (DSIS)

These are income stream products which will enjoy the earnings tax exemption but will not have any immediate pension payment obligations until the end of a deferral period (say when the purchaser attains age 80). The requirements which a financial product has to satisfy in order to qualify as a DSIS are yet to be determined. Presumably there will be additional sub-regulations to 1.05 & 1.06 of the SISR. These products will be either deferred annuities issued by life insurance companies or “grouped self annuities” in which a cohort of pensioners in a large super fund forms a group so that any account balance released by early death of a member will be used to underwrite the payment guarantee. Presumably there will be restrictions on exiting the contract/cohort – as otherwise there will be no profits to transfer from those that die early to those that survive.

These products cannot be issued by SMSFs. Presumably the justification for excluding SMSFs from this type of income stream is that (a) there is no counterparty which will shoulder the longevity risk (in the case of deferred annuities – it is the issuing life insurance/registered organisation) or (b) that an SMSF does not have a sufficient number of members which can be grouped into a cohort where the longevity risk is shared amongst the cohort.

However, excluding SMSFs from DSIS may significantly reduce the attractiveness of SMSFs. A member concerned by longevity risk with $800,000 in super could buy an account-based pension with $400,000 and with $400,000 buy a DSIS where the deferral period ends at age 80. Under the new rules the $400,000 invested in the DSIS will from day 1 enjoy the “earning tax exemption” and only commence payment at when the deferral period ends – say when the investor is aged 80. (Strictly, if the DSIS is purchased before an unrestricted release condition has been satisfied, the earnings tax exemption only applies from the date an unrestricted release conditions occurs and the value of the DSIS will be credited to the transfer balance account when the earnings tax exemption applies to the product.)

The longevity risk of account-based pensions is magnified (if not created) by the minimum drawdown requirements in later years.
If the Government wishes to address the above discrepancy between the treatment of SMSFs and DSISs, the following changes could be made to the rules:

  • reduce the excessive mandatory drawdown rate in later years or
  • allow SMSFs to issue DSIS (albeit there will be no payment guarantee). To maintain integrity, the DSIS in an SMSF could operate by having the income stream commuted on death (if the account has not previously exhausted) and commutation payment made to the estate of the deceased member.

Transition to Retirement Income Streams (TRIS)

TRIS on the hand will not be recognised as a retirement phase income stream going forward and will lose their earnings tax exemption. It should be noted that for efficiency and economies of scale reasons, all assets backing pension liabilities are typically pooled into common investment asset pool(s). Members in large superannuation funds typically own units in these investment asset pools. The value of their account based income stream is determined by the number of units they hold in the particular asset pool x price. Earnings tax if it were to be calculated would be calculated at this investment asset pool level and not by pension type or down to member level.

To administer this measure, Funds would need to be able to attribute and isolate any earnings tax to just members in that asset pool that have a TRIS income stream. This will require asset segregation of the existing asset pool (shared by TRIS and non-TRIS members) with possibly CGT relief required in certain circumstances. Furthermore, the unit price would typically capture realised and unrealised income & gains and the earnings tax payable each year should be limited to just income and realised gains only and not unrealised.

The Institute is concerned with the cost and effort involved to deal with this particular class of pension and members. We submit that taxing the income stream benefits that these TRIS members received could achieve the same objective and not require any investment restructure and asset segregation. As an alternative, members who were preservation age to age 59 could lose entitlement to the 15% tax offset on their assessable income stream benefit, whereas those aged 60 and over but not retired could be taxed 15% on their income stream benefits.

Administrative issues

Commutation Authority

The Institute is concerned that the current 30 day time limit provided to superannuation income stream provider to comply is not reasonable. Particularly if as outlined in Paragraph 1.131 of the Explanatory Memoranda they are also required to make reasonable efforts to consult with the member first, to seek their wish/preference as to whether to roll the excess back to the accumulation phase or cash it out. We would submit that 90 days would be a more reasonable time frame to allow member and provider to discuss and process the request. Furthermore, there may be instances in which assets supporting the particular income stream may be temporarily illiquid or non-commutable and require more time for an orderly redemption in order to avoid unnecessary penalties and/or break costs.

In the event there is a failure by the superannuation income stream provider to comply, the consequence is that the investment earnings supporting that particular income stream will cease to be exempt from tax and deemed to be effective from the start of the financial year and for the whole income year. It should be noted that this particular calculation is extremely difficult in relation to members in a large superannuation fund whereby their interest in the fund is based on their share in a single investment asset pool (as noted above in relation TRIS). A failure to comply with a commutation authority has the effect of retrospectively deeming certain member(s) as not belonging to this particular tax exempt cohort. Significant build is required by large superannuation funds to overhaul their systems to calculate earnings tax based on the tax attribute of a member (i.e. member level, as opposed to investment asset pool level). At the very least, one would need to track what income and realised gains were attributed to each member in the investment asset pool, when currently there is no income distribution made to these members.

* * * *

If you would like to discuss any of the above, please contact either me or Tax Counsel, Thilini Wickramasuriya, on 02 8223 0044.

Yours sincerely

Arthur Athanasiou
President

1 http://sjm.ministers.treasury.gov.au/media-release/105-2016/

Our Call For Action

Save Our Super calls for all Federal parliamentarians to promote and support superannuation policies and legislation which contain grandfathering provisions that maintain the previous entitlements of those Australians who will be significantly affected by major rule changes to the then existing superannuation provisions.

Submission on second tranche of superannuation exposure drafts

10 October 2016

SUBMISSION ON SECOND TRANCHE OF SUPERANNUATION EXPOSURE DRAFTS

Terrence O’Brien and Jack Hammond QC, on behalf of themselves and Save Our Super

According to Treasurer Scott Morrison:

“One of our key drivers when contemplating potential superannuation reforms is stability and certainty, especially in the retirement phase. That is good for people who are looking 30 years down the track and saying is superannuation a good idea for me? If they are going to change the rules at the other end when you are going to be living off it then it is understandable that they might get spooked out of that as an appropriate channel for their investment. That is why I fear that the approach of taxing in that retirement phase penalises Australians who have put money into superannuation under the current rules – under the deal that they thought was there. It may not be technical retrospectivity but it certainly feels that way. It is effective retrospectivity, the tax technicians and superannuation tax technicians may say differently. But when you just look at it that is the great risk.”

 Address to the SMSF 2016 National Conference, Adelaide, 18 February 2016 (emphasis added).

“Now that we have a new PM (Malcolm Turnbull) and new treasurer (Scott Morrison), and newly re-elected Coalition government, anything is possible based on the recent super changes announced in the 2016 Federal Budget.”

Trish Power, SuperGuide: Tax free super for over 60s, except for some, 23 August 2016 (emphasis added).

Declaration of interests:  Terrence O’Brien is a retired public servant receiving a super pension from a defined benefit, ‘untaxed’ fund.  He would be adversely affected by some of the measures in the second tranche.

Jack Hammond QC is in the process of retiring from his barrister’s practice.  He will be adversely affected by some of the measures in the second tranche.

Contents

1. Summary 2
2. Inadequate time for public comment 6
3. Inconsistency of measures with Government’s stated objectives 6
4. Superannuation savers: tax minimizers and estate planners? 7
5. The complexity of the Transfer Balance Caps 8
6. One forgotten benefit of simplicity: compliance costs 9
7. Faulty arguments for reducing super incentives: high cost, unfairness and unsustainability 11
Cost: measures not fit for purpose 11
‘Fairness’: more dimensions than vertical redistribution alone 12
Sustainability: an empty concept for super concessions 14
8. ‘Effective retrospectivity’ is pervasive throughout the measures 15
9. Super tax increases without grandfathering change the moral landscape 18
10. Is $1.6 million a defensible cap? 19
11. Complexity and risk for the taxpayer: the case for safeguards 20
12. Bereavement 20
13. Treatment of defined benefit retirement income streams 20
14. Lower minimum drawdown amounts on super pensions 22
15. Innovative income streams: more costs of ‘effective retrospectivity’ 22
16. Conclusions 23

 

1.      Summary

The intended measures reverse the strategic direction of the Costello reforms of 2006-07 by circuitously, but in effect, re-imposing tax on retirement incomes  — so far, on those self-funded retirees who over decades and under current law have saved more than $1.6 million. It will serve as a precedent for those who favour future increases.

The new measures effectively impose tax on the earnings on superannuation savings over $1.6 million accumulated for up to 40 years and now lawfully in retirement accounts that are tax-free under current law.  In over 100 years of Australian superannuation law, no such earnings tax on retirement capital has ever been imposed previously. To enable that tax, the Government proposes a complex new structure of ‘transfer balance accounts’, ‘general transfer balance caps’, ‘personal transfer balance caps’ and ‘excess transfer balance’ taxes to claim that the new earnings tax is not on the ‘retirement phase’ as newly defined, but rather on the redirection of retirement funds into an accumulation account.

Consequent on this unexplained choice of approach, the measures are absurdly complex. In one fell swoop, they more than undo the simplification gains and the administration and compliance cost reductions from the Costello reforms.  In 2006, Treasurer Costello took an excessively complex super system which taxed retirement income in up to 8 different parts in 7 different ways, and simplified it to today’s system.  Reducing previous super earnings taxation complexity down to today’s comparative simplicity took 144 paragraphs in the 2006 Explanatory Memorandum. In 2016, Treasurer Morrison’s re-complication of the taxation of retirement income — just one chapter of the Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials on the transfer balance cap — takes 269 paragraphs, almost 90% longer.

Given the complexity and pervasive effects of the changes, the 13 days allowed for public consultation on some 234 pages of material is derisory.  Treasurer Costello’s reforms provided a 4 month window for comment, and garnered some 1,500 written submissions. (In the little time available, this submission has only scratched the surface of the first chapter and part of the eighth chapter of the 10 chapter Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials.)

The Government should provide a statement (as is soon to be mandatory under its own first tranche legislation) on the consistency or otherwise of the proposed measures with its objectives for superannuation. Those objectives, we are told, are ‘to provide income in retirement to substitute or supplement the age pension’, and five subordinate objectives, one of which is to ‘be simple, efficient and provide safeguards’. The Government statement should also include quantification of the compatibility of the measures with its own stated objectives, with particular attention to the combined effect on super and age pension cost, levels of self-sufficiency in retirement and retirement living standards.

A statement of consistency with objectives would test both the validity of the proposed measures, and the practicality of the stated objectives. Before changing the super law, a key issue to enumerate in a transparent and quantified manner is whether the total impact over time of all the measures reduces government costs of the retirement system in net terms, or (as seems likely) worsens the budget position over time through destroying confidence in super and increasing resort to the age pension. The destruction of confidence arises through the announcement of tax increases of a type that Treasurer Morrison  called ‘effectively retrospective’ and the abandonment of customary grandfathering.[i]

The measures are ‘effectively retrospective’ in that they re-assign pension account capital whose earnings are now lawfully tax-free. If transferred to an accumulation account they will be taxed. The measures thus instantly reduce the living standards of some who have already retired, and who have only trusted their life savings to super because of the protection of the current tax laws.  The measures also blindside those too close to retirement to change their legitimate saving plans. The measures adversely affecting these groups should be appropriately grandfathered.

Grandfathering in such cases has been the sound practice of all governments for all other significant super tax increases over at least the last 40 years. Grandfathering is necessary to preserve trust in super and in future law-making for super.

If grandfathering is abandoned, it alters the moral landscape of obedience to taxation law and reduces the legitimacy citizens vest in government.

None of the Government documents on its measures mention compliance costs, still less enumerates them. Contrary to repeated claims that 96% (or 99%) of individuals with superannuation will either be better off or unaffected as a result of the changes, every super saver who seeks to access significant life savings in the retirement phase will be adversely affected by having to create a transfer balance account and to monitor their position relative to a general transfer balance cap and their personal transfer balance cap.

Costly professional financial advice will again become essential at every superannuation decision point. Total additional compliance costs imposed on super savers will be very large.  For Self-Managed Super Funds alone, they could easily total $1.5 to $2 billion in 2017, with lesser recurrent costs annually thereafter.

The Government states as reasons for its measures the allegedly high cost of existing concessions, unfairness in their distribution, and ‘unsustainability’ over time.  All three claims are strongly disputed, and should be reexamined objectively.

The tax increases take effect when global growth prospects are poor and falling, and many interest rates are near-zero or negative in real terms.  Self-funded retirees now face an era of ‘return-free risk’, so the increase in complexity, compliance cost and taxes is particularly badly timed.

By far the greatest complexity (and much of the ‘effective retrospectivity’) in the second tranche arises from the transfer balance account concept, the transfer balance caps and their associated provisions. It has never been explained why that approach is desirable, and why such complexity is necessary.

The transfer caps and associated measures give draconian powers to the Taxation Commissioner, and impose heavy penalties on taxpayers who may be defeated by the complexity of the measures. If the measures proceed, Parliament should require the Commissioner to provide a safeguard to all savers with personal transfer balances over $500,000 by issuing binding advance statements of their transfer cap position well before the starting date of the measures, and with timely notification every year thereafter.

The proposed increased taxes on defined benefit pensions are amongst the most complex parts of the measures. Their many components make it impossible to judge whether their combined impact is more or less commensurate with the increased taxes on self-funded retirees with high transfer balances.  Almost all defined benefit schemes have long been closed to closed to new entrants. If the Government grandfathered its policy to increase tax on those already retired and receiving tax-free benefits from taxed funds with assets above $1.6 million supporting their pensions, it would be unnecessary to grapple with the ‘broadly commensurate’ treatment of defined benefit schemes.

The Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials introduces a novel idea:  to extend the earnings tax exemption that the Budget removes from current retirement income streams arising from a transfer balance cap above $1.6 million.  The extended concession would apply to innovative lifetime products such as ‘deferred products’ and ‘group self-annuities’ that may emerge in the future. But absent grandfathering on current tax increases, why would anyone embrace new products with even longer vulnerability to future policy change?

Public consultations to date on these complex matters have been manifestly inadequate, If the proposed legislation is passed by the House of Representatives, the Senate should subject it to careful scrutiny. It should refer the whole of the Government’s proposed superannuation package to a Senate Committee. The Senate Committee should invite and consider public submissions and objections. The assumptions which underpin the changes should be open to public challenge.

The government should go back to the drawing board on its measures.  If, having reviewed the weak basis of claims about the cost, unfairness and unsustainability of super concessions, the Government still wants to raise more revenue from self-funded retirees, it should do so more fairly by appropriate grandfathering.

2.     Inadequate time for public comment

For this second tranche of legislation as for the first tranche, the time allowed for consultation is derisorily short.  Self-funded retirees and savers with vital interests in the superannuation system have been given just 13 days to consider 234 pages, 57,600 words of very complex, far-reaching proposed legislation. That makes a mockery of the concept of public consultation. In at least two specific and very technical areas, complex matters that have defeated policy advisers, super industry and financial advisors over four months have been flicked to the general public on an impossibly short timetable.[ii] More draft legislation and explanatory material is still to be released.

In the limited time available, this submission focusses just on the Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials for the second tranche, and mostly on just Chapter 1, the 66 page explanation of the transfer balance cap at the heart of the tax increases. The other 9 Chapters of the Explanatory Materials await proper consultation opportunities in the future, such as before a Senate Committee.

Australian super lawmaking processes have deteriorated to the cost of public confidence in super.  Contrast the current exercise with the planning for and consultation around the last major change of strategic direction in Australian super law, the Costello Super Simplification exercise of 2006 and 2007.[iii]  A substantial discussion paper was issued with  the May 2006 Budget announcement of the measures, with an extended consultation over four months until September 2006.[iv] There was keen interest to comment: more than 1,500 written submissions and more than 3,500 phone calls from across the community.

3.     Inconsistency of measures with Government’s stated objectives

The Government claims its measures have been guided by its soon-to-be-legislated primary objective for superannuation,

.. to provide income in retirement that substitute or supplements the age pension.[v]

What does that mean? Would a policy change be considered successful if it discouraged super savers from achieving higher savings balances and created uncertainty and costs for future super savings, while encouraging reliance on the super guarantee levy and topping up retirement income with a part pension?  That reduction in self-reliance seems to be the likely effect of the proposed measures.  The Government also specifies 5 subordinate objectives which include “be simple, efficient and provide safeguards”, to be traded off against each other and balanced against the principal objective using unspecified processes and weights. [vi]

Compare those bewilderingly ambiguous objectives with the Howard-Costello era objective for superannuation simplification:

The policy objective is to assist and encourage people to achieve a higher standard of living in retirement than would be possible from the age pension alone.[vii]

Or another possibility, suggested by the Institute of Public Affairs:

The objective of the superannuation system is to ensure that as many Australians as possible take personal responsibility to save for their own retirement. The age pension provides a safety net for those who are unable to provide for themselves in retirement.[viii]

Terrence O’Brien has argued in his submission to Treasury of 16 September 2016 on the first tranche of measures (which includes the legislation to state the Government objectives above) that the Government’s six objectives are, in practice, meaningless and unworkable. We favour adopting the IPA’s suggested alternative.[ix] But the Government’s six proposed objectives should at least be tested with the current superannuation proposals. The Government should provide a quantified statement showing the compatibility of the measures with its own stated objectives, as will become compulsory from 2017 if the Superannuation (Objective) Bill 2016 becomes law.

There will be four major impacts of the first and second tranche measures.

First, they will reduce super self-reliance and increase reliance on the age pension: For example, Tony Negline illustrates that for a married couple there is severely diminishing returns from saving more than about $340,000 in super, as that amount maximizes the combined retirement income from a super pension and a part age pension. One could save almost 5 times more to reach the super target of $1.6 million and only  gain a little more than twice the retirement income.[x] The Government’s measures to induce saving above $1.6 million back into the accumulation phase paying 15% tax will further weight the trade-off against self-reliance and saving in super.  Negline concludes the best strategy is to save in super only the mimimum required by the super guarantee levy and to invest in the best (and best maintained) home one can afford.

Second, they will reduce trust in superannuation as a safe vehicle for lifetime savings and a secure living standard in self-funded retirement: Terrence O’Brien’s report for the Centre for Independent Studies, Grandfathering super tax increases, explains how the Government’s proposed approach breaches at least 40 years of good practice in grandfathering super tax increases and will severely damage confidence in super saving.[xi]

Third, they will increase resort to investment outside superannuation, for example in negatively geared property as well as the incentive to invest in the principal residence noted above.[xii]

Finally, as a consequence of the foregoing point, they will decrease the efficient allocation of scarce savings through efficient capital markets. [xiii]

4.     Superannuation savers: tax minimizers and estate planners?

The Government has argued that its measures seek to “reduce the extent to which superannuation is used for tax minimization and estate planning.” (e.g. Treasury Laws Amendment (Fair and sustainable superannuation) Bill 2016: Exposure draft explanatory materials, p 8 para 1.6)

It is hard to make sense of this claim.

Because of the disincentive to long-term saving from a progressive tax on nominal income, the existence of a generous age pension, and the 40-year restriction on access to super savings, for over 100 years governments have used tax incentives to support  superannuation.  In responding to those deliberate incentives as Parliament intended, anybody who has a superannuation account is in a  sense a ‘tax minimizer’.

Most have thought (since at least Menzies’ Forgotten People speech of 1942[xiv]) that the purpose of super tax incentives was to encourage thrift and self-reliance.  Worse things can happen to a country than its workers practice thrift and save for their own retirement, with any excess for their children’s benefit.

Referring to super savers as tax minimizers and estate planners is not a guide sound policy analysis or good policy.

5.     The complexity of the Transfer Balance Caps

The Government documentation nowhere explains why the objective of raising more revenue from some self-funded retirees and from those saving to become self-funded, requires the inevitably complex and ‘effectively retrospective’ approach of:

  • moving funds already lawfully placed in a retirement account into a new transfer balance account, and
  • forcing any excess in the transfer balance account over $1.6 million into an ‘accumulation account’ and taxing the income on that account at 15%.

It is helpful to look below the surface to the reality of the measures. On the surface, the Government argues that there is no real change in the measure: 96% (or 99%) will be better off or unaffected under all the Budget measures, saved capital is preserved, funds are left inside superannuation framework, etc.[xv] But the reality is that the measure reduces living standards from  lifetime savings made under existing law and already funding retirement free of tax (if from a taxed fund); under the new law it reduces the retiree’s living standard by subjecting  any ‘excess’ savings over the transfer balance cap to 15% tax on earnings, and without grandfathering.

This new tax on fund earnings within the retirement phase is unprecedented in over 100 years of specific Australian taxation measures governing superannuation.[xvi]

The additional tax has the simple effect of reducing retirement income by an ‘effectively retrospective’ change in the law.

The specific means for applying the transfer balance account through general and personal transfer balance caps quickly turns inevitable complexity into absurd complexity.

When the Costello simplification measures were legislated in 2006, the Explanatory Memorandum explained the full gamut of the new taxation of retirement income streams in just 144 paragraphs, most devoted to mapping the previous law’s complicated treatments into the current streamlined treatments under the laws within which retirees have now organized their savings.[xvii]

The new proposed treatment of retirement income takes 269 paragraphs of attempted explanation in the Treasury Laws Amendment (Fair and Sustainable Superannuation) Bill 2016: Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials, with several acknowledgements that complex areas have yet to be settled and seeking further public input (though obviously not within the time frame given for consultation).

So it is taking Treasurer Morrison about 90% more verbiage to explain the re-complication of the taxation of retirement income as it took Treasurer Costello to explain simplification of the status quo ante.

6.     One forgotten benefit of simplicity: compliance costs

Key Government measures in the second tranche reverse the strategic direction of the 2006-2007 Howard-Costello superannuation simplification reforms by reintroducing, in effect, the taxation of end benefits.

If the second tranche were implemented, it would reintroduce such complexity in superannuation law that the superannuation tax structure would be returned in one fell swoop to a worse state than immediately before the Howard-Costello reforms. With such complexity, introduced with limited time for consultation, comes the high risk of unforeseen consequences and the need for further legislative changes in future, presently unforeseeable as to detail. This risk is a further cloud over the credibility of super as a repository of life savings and a foundation for self-funded retirement.

Since the lessons of even a decade ago are now apparently lost, it is worth remembering the recent experience of complexity in superannuation end-benefit taxation:

The report of the “Taskforce on Reducing Regulatory Burdens on Business, Rethinking Regulation”, recommended that high priority be given to comprehensive simplification of the tax rules for superannuation benefits. The report highlighted that the greatest area of complexity is the taxation of end-benefits.Superannuation benefits tax is by far the most complicated and is the tax that individuals must confront when entering or contemplating retirement. At present, it is difficult for anyone to understand how their superannuation benefits will be taxed.A lump sum may include up to eight different parts taxed in seven different ways.The complexity of the benefits tax arrangements not only affects retirees. It affects individual decisions concerning additional superannuation contributions. It also adds to the administration costs of superannuation funds.[xviii]

The Government has repeatedly claimed that 96% (or sometimes, 99%) of individuals with superannuation will either be better off or unaffected as a result of the changes.

The reality is that every potential self-funded retiree who one day seeks to enter the superannuation retirement phase will be adversely affected by the complexity and compliance costs of creating transfer balance accounts and monitoring their saving relative to the general transfer balance cap and the evolution of their personal transfer balance cap.  Costly professional financial advice will again be essential at every superannuation decision point.

The administration costs for the Australian Taxation Office provide one illustration of the complexity of the approach, with a Budget allowance of $4.4 million in 2016-17 to prepare for the transfer balance cap and associated measures.[xix] But the administrative costs pale in comparison to the compliance costs imposed on savers and retirees.  Compliance costs are nowhere mentioned, let alone quantified, in the Government’s documentation.

What might be the order of magnitude of compliance costs? Let’s assume, for the sake of illustration, that all 557,000 self-managed super funds need to seek financial advice on the impact of the new measures by 30 June 2017.[xx]  The compliance costs for SMSFs are estimated to be $3000-$4000 per fund. [xxi]   The total extra cost for SMSFs in 2017 could be of the order of  $1.5 to $2 billion dollars.

There are also 14.8 million individual Australians with super accounts.  If we assume fund members aged 50 or older and with appreciable super savings similarly seek advice, and that the simpler issues raised for super fund members cost $300-$600 in professional advice, that might add another $0.5 billion to the advice costs incurred by SMSFs.

Of course to that should be added the costs to savers and retirees themselves of providing the organized information on their affairs necessary for financial advisers to ply their trade.[xxii] Depending on the valuation of taxpayers’ time, that could easily add another 25% or more to arrive at a total compliance cost.

Taxpayers who may be affected by the tax increases and super restrictions should certainly seek financial advice before 30 June 2017.   Even assuming the availability of professional advice in the face of a very large surge in demand, it will be difficult for the large numbers of people with multiple super accounts to obtain a consolidated statement of their exposure to the transfer balance caps in time for the intended initiation of the tax increases. (Over 40% of the 14.8 million super savers have more than one account; 8% have four or more.)

While for many, actions will be required by 30 June 2017 or urgently within a few months thereafter, there will likely be continuing compliance costs and the need to seek financial advice – in some cases (such as SMSFs, or those near their personal balance caps) perhaps year by year. In other cases, recurrent compliance costs may be less frequent.  But the annual compliance costs in perpetuity will certainly be non-trivial, and vastly exceed the benchmark achieved after the Costello simplification reforms.

Let’s estimate, conservatively, that total initial compliance costs amount to $2 billion in 2016-17, and another $1 billion in 2017-18. These numbers may be scaled against the Budget measures which are said to raise less that $6 billion gross over the forward estimates to 2019-20.  In net terms after creation of the new tax expenditures on super in the tranche one measures, the net revenue gain to 2019-20 was said to be less than $3 billion.

So on conservative estimates, the net revenue gains from the Budget measures over 4 years would be roughly equalled by the initial compliance costs to savers and retirees. Of course, our estimates of compliance costs are just a first attempt to scale the problem.  Parliament should require the Government to produce explicit, transparent, official estimates of the compliance costs of the measures.

All these administrative and compliance costs are being generated in a legislative package that includes the Superannuation (Objective) Bill 2016, whose explanatory material adds that among five supplementary objectives to the primary objective (“to provide income in retirement to substitute or supplement the age pension”), one that requires that the system should “be simple, efficient and provide safeguards”.[xxiii]

7.     Faulty arguments for reducing super incentives:  high cost, unfairness and unsustainability

The Government claims the second tranche measures (and indeed the first tranche measures) are all necessary to make super tax treatment less expensive to revenue, more sustainable and fairer — indeed, “even fairer” than initially proposed.[xxiv]  Those claims have never been properly evidenced or enumerated. A Senate Committee inquiry would enable those claims to be tested.

Cost: measures not fit for purpose

The foundation of the argument for reducing super concessions is their allegedly excessive total cost.  However super tax incentives are not give-aways.  As expressed in the 2009 Henry Review, Australia’s future tax system:

The essential reason for exempting lifetime savings or taxing them at a lower rate is that income taxation creates a bias against savings. The income taxation of savings therefore discriminates against taxpayers who save. They pay a higher lifetime tax bill than people with similar earnings who choose to save less. As savings can be thought of as deferred consumption, the longer the person saves and reinvests, the greater the implicit tax on future consumption …… For a person who works today and saves, taxing savings also reduces the benefit from working.The increasing implicit tax on future consumption provides an argument to tax longer-term lifetime savings at a lower rate. An individual can undertake lifetime saving through a variety of savings vehicles, but there are asset types that are more conducive or related to lifetime savings: namely superannuation and owner-occupied housing.[xxv]

That distortion is exacerbated by the provision of an aged pension with a generous income and asset tests:

Pension costs as a percentage of wages are at the highest level they have ever been, having nearly doubled over the past 40 years The means test has become much more generous: the upper limit of the assets was just under 12 times the full rate of the pension in 1911, whereas today the ratio between the single homeowner assets test cutoff is nearly 35 times the full rate (despite the massive increase in the full rate of the pension over that time).[xxvi]

Long-term saving such as superannuation would be non-existent without extensive tax incentives.

However as the Treasurer has noted the annual (gross) tax expenditures on super may be $30 billion, or they may be $11 billion.[xxvii]  Indeed, according to separate studies  by Ken Henry and Jeremy Cooper, they may be less still in gross terms, and less again (or even a net budget benefit) once the impact on age pension uptake is considered.  As Robert Carling of the Centre for Independent Studies has argued,

Statements often made about the huge fiscal cost of Australia’s superannuation tax concessions are based on the comprehensive income tax benchmark for measuring tax expenditures, but the characteristics of superannuation make it unsuitable for such a benchmark. The most appropriate benchmark is an expenditure tax under which contributions and fund earnings would be tax-exempt but end-benefits fully taxed. When measured against such a benchmark, tax expenditure on superannuation is much lower than commonly believed, or non-existent.[xxviii]

‘Fairness’: more dimensions than vertical redistribution alone

The Treasurer  has noted that the top deciles of taxpayers get the most benefit from tax incentives to save in superannuation; this may be called the ‘Duncan Storrar effect’.[xxix]

You all know high-income earners generally have far more capacity, and inclination, to save for retirement. This is a good thing, this is a very good thing, it’s not something that should be demonised or seen as some sort of nefarious practice. Which is, I think, often a point that is implied when people make criticisms of these things. I think it is great that people are out there saving for their own future. I think it is tremendous.[xxx]

It has fallen to the CIS’s Robert Carling to illustrate that the greater utilization of super tax concessions by the relatively rich – usually reported without any context, as if a self-evident scandal – is roughly proportionate to the contributions of each decile to the income tax take (see charts on following page).[xxxi]  Indeed, the richest 10 per cent utilize somewhat less than ‘their share’ of the super concessions.

There is also a mistaken tendency to regard ‘fairness’ as a one-dimensional concept requiring nothing more than vertical redistribution from the relatively rich to the relatively poor. This often seems to be pursued without any logical limit short of perfect equality, and disregarding other dimensions of fairness made worse along the way. In this common view, it is not sufficient merely to maintain Australia’s existing progressive tax/benefit system, even though in  comparison with other OECD economies, both tax and benefits components of the system are highly progressive. [xxxii] 2nd-tranche-graph-1In contrast to this one dimensional view of fairness as no more than vertical redistribution, most Australians understand that fairness is a multi-dimensional concept.  It is certainly fair that we as individual and as a community provide for the indigent.  But equally importantly, it is also fair that those who work hardest and bear the greatest risks in economic life should gain the greatest reward after paying their lawfully imposed taxes.  It is fair that far-sightedness in providing for the future is rewarded.  It is fair that thrift is rewarded.  Nor are all dimensions of fairness positive; fairness can have elements of disapprobation: for example, many feel that the feckless or those unwilling to work should not be able to free-ride on their more industrious fellow citizens. Finally, most consider it fair that people — and governments — should honour their commitments.

It is these broader concepts of fairness that explain why so many are critical of the Government’s claim that it is fair to reduce by ‘effectively retrospective’ tax increases the living standards of those self-funded retirees who have responded as governments have intended to incentives to save in super. They are equally critical of the Government’s intent to restrict, without time to adjust, the savings in super of those older workers too close to retirement to change their life savings plans.

Sustainability: an empty concept for super concessions

There has been no discussion of what the notion of ‘sustainability’ might mean in the case of the Costello-era simplification of super taxation that levied tax at the contribution and accumulation stage of superannuation, but allowed retirees over 60 who had contributed to taxed funds, untouchable during their working lives, to draw down their savings in retirement without further taxation.  (This is the same model as for the taxation of bank account savings – no one thinks that if they need to withdraw $100 from an ATM, they should receive less than that because of a third stage of taxation.)

Of course, if people save more in super and pay more super contributions tax (as they have been doing, following Government compulsion or incentives), then they will earn more in the accumulation phase (and pay still more tax on that income).  Finally, they will enjoy higher super balances in retirement.  In what sense does the lack of a third stage of taxation on higher retirement balances become ‘unsustainable’ as the amount of super savings rise? Would it be argued that the taxation treatment of bank account savings has become unsustainable as bank accounts have grown?

The costing of the Costello simplification reforms was part of a well-considered and consultative process.  In the 2006-07 Budget documentation the costs of the super concessions were estimated over the forward estimates period, and those estimates were refined again on the release of the final simplification measures.  There is no evidence the subsequent evolution of the costs of super concessions, properly benchmarked, has been in any sense unanticipated.

8.     ‘Effective retrospectivity’ is pervasive throughout the measures

If there were no concessional taxation arrangements for superannuation, the current system would not exist. A progressive tax on nominal income and a generous age pension heavily penalise long-term saving, and there is no longer and more restricted form of long-term saving than superannuation. A saver’s consumption is locked away over some 40 years of a working life, and must then sustain living standards for some 30 year thereafter.[xxxiii]

The tax treatment of super is specified in law over all three stages of the super life cycle:  contributions, accumulation and retirement. Savers penalised by the Budget measures would not have accumulated such high balances locked untouchably into superannuation if they had had foreknowledge of how the tax treatment in the retirement phase would be increased after they had retired.

The Budget measures are not just changing the rules after the game has started; they are changing them well into the fourth quarter. That is the context in which Treasurer Morrison coined the useful term ‘effective retrospectivity’:

One of our key drivers when contemplating potential superannuation reforms is stability and certainty, especially in the retirement phase. That is good for people who are looking 30 years down the track and saying is superannuation a good idea for me? If they are going to change the rules at the other end when you are going to be living off it then it is understandable that they might get spooked out of that as an appropriate channel for their investment. That is why I fear that the approach of taxing in that retirement phase penalises Australians who have put money into superannuation under the current rules – under the deal that they thought was there. It may not be technical retrospectivity but it certainly feels that way. It is effective retrospectivity, the tax technicians and superannuation tax technicians may say differently. But when you just look at it that is the great risk.  (Emphasis added.)[xxxiv]

Because of the typical 40-year length of commitment to making super contributions and the unique restrictions on accessing super savings, people need a lengthy adjustment period to respond to any adverse changes to policy. The same is true of the closely related issue of age pension changes. That is why past successful significant changes to retirement parameters – such as the means test of the age pension, the pension eligibility age, the superannuation preservation age or increased taxation of superannuation –  have generally been undertaken gradually, with advance notice, extended consultation and often with ‘grandfathering’ of existing arrangements to prevent disadvantaging workers close to retirement, or retirees who have limited or no opportunity to change their lifetime savings strategies.

To induce savers to lock away savings on the basis of an existing tax package over all three stages and then to raise tax on those already retired or too close to retirement to change their savings plans, not only reduces the living standards of those directly affected; it also destroys every saver’s trust in super (and in government law-making). That in turn reduces everybody’s preparedness to risk unpredictable future legislative penalties on self-funded retirement, and increases the risk-management attractions of blending lower super balances with more reliance on the age part-pension.

The challenges of facilitating gradual increases in super taxes while not destroying confidence in super were addressed most thoughtfully by the late Justice Kenneth Asprey, who was commissioned by the outgoing McMahon Government to report on the Australian taxation system. Asprey made his Committee’s final report to the Whitlam Government.  His recommendations at first had little apparent effect, but it they drove all the major advances in Australian tax reform over the following quarter century:

The capital gains tax, the fringe benefits tax, dividend imputation, the foreign tax credit system, the goods and services tax (he called it a “broad-based value-added tax”) — all were proposed in the Asprey report.[xxxv]

The Asprey insights into the need to grandfather super tax increases, and his principles for how to do that while preserving necessary policy flexibility to respond to changing circumstances are shown in the following Box.

More recently, the Gillard Government’s Superannuation Charter Group led by Jeremy Cooper addressed concerns about the future of the super savings and the way policy changes have been made.[xxxvi] The Charter Group reported to the second Rudd Government in July 2013 with useful proposals in the nature of a ‘superannuation constitution’ that would codify the nature of the compact between governments and savers, including:

  • In order to promote confidence in the long-term benefits, no change to superannuation should be regarded as urgent.
  • People should have sufficient confidence in the regulatory settings and their evolution to trust their savings to superannuation, including making voluntary contributions.
  • Relevant considerations, when assessing policy against the principle of certainty, include the ability for people to plan for retirement and adjust to superannuation policy changes with confidence.
  • People should have sufficient time to alter their arrangements in response to proposed policy changes, particularly those people nearing retirement who have made long-term plans on the basis of the existing settings.

Box:  Grandfathering principles:  Asprey Taxation Review,  Chapter 21,  1975

Principle 1

21.9. Finally, and most importantly, it must be borne in mind that the matters with which the Committee is here dealing involve long-term commitments entered into by taxpayers on the basis of the existing taxation structure. It would be unfair to such persons if a significantly different taxation structure were to be introduced without adequate and reasonable transitional arrangements. ………

Principle 2

21.61. …..Many people, particularly those nearing retirement, have made their plans for the future on the assumption that the amounts they receive on retirement would continue to be taxed on the present basis. The legitimate expectations of such people deserve the utmost consideration. To change suddenly to a harsher basis of taxing such receipts would generate justifiable complaints that the legislation was retrospective in nature, since the amounts concerned would normally have accrued over a considerable period—possibly over the entire working life of the person concerned. …..

Principle 3

21.64. There is nonetheless a limit to the extent to which concern over such retrospectivity can be allowed to influence recommendations for a fundamental change in the tax structure. Pushed to its extreme such an argument leads to a legislative straitjacket where it is impossible to make changes to any revenue law for fear of disadvantaging those who have made their plans on the basis of the existing legislation.   …..

Principle 4

21.81. ….  [I]t is necessary to distinguish legitimate expectations from mere hopes. A person who is one day from retirement obviously has a legitimate expectation that his retiring allowance or superannuation benefit which may have accrued over forty years or more will be accorded the present treatment. On the other hand, it is unrealistic and unnecessary to give much weight to the expectations of the twenty-year-old as to the tax treatment of his ultimate retirement benefits.

Principle 5

21.82. In theory the approach might be that only amounts which can be regarded as accruing after the date of the legislation should be subject to the new treatment. This would prevent radically different treatment of the man who retires one day after that date and the man who retires one day before. It would also largely remove any complaints about retroactivity in the new legislation ….

These Charter Group suggestions would also appear to support the use of grandfathering in the case of the Government’s proposed tax increases.  It observed:The Charter Group has formed the view that it is changes to tax concessions and entitlements (for example, to the preservation age or the ability to access super) that are most likely to affect member confidence and call for the additional processes and protections proposed by the Charter.[xxxvii] (emphasis added)

Further details showing how  grandfathering adverse changes to superannuation and related retirement income parameters has been used over the last 40 years are contained in Terrence O’Brien’s paper for the Centre for Independent Studies,  Grandfathering super tax increases.[xxxviii]

9.     Super tax increases without grandfathering change the moral landscape

Ultimately, citizens do not pay tax only because the law says they must. Greek laws say Greeks must pay tax, but many don’t.  Russian laws say Russians must pay tax, but many don’t.

Ultimately, citizens in a functioning democracy pay tax because they believe their democratically elected government has legitimacy, and its laws should be respected.[xxxix] Citizens expect governments to be bound by their own laws, just as those laws bind citizens.

‘Effectively retrospective’ changes in super tax laws alter the moral landscape. If a Government passes laws to encourage lifetime savings to be locked in to super, but then changes the rules to suit its budget needs to the detriment of those who relied and acted on the basis of the existing laws, that sends citizens a message: government will change the law with ‘effective retrospectivity’ to the citizen’s disadvantage whenever it wants to.

How is the citizen to respond? Most likely, citizens will be less likely to concede legitimacy to the Government’s new laws. In a world where citizens can lawfully form discretionary family trusts, buy and equip more expensive principal residences, negatively gear rental property and make other adjustments which lawfully minimize their tax, they will be more inclined to do so under the changed laws than if the Government had honoured the laws it had passed, or grandfathered any changes in them adverse to citizens who had relied on, and acted on, the then-current law.

For these reasons, the estimated revenue gains from the tranche two measure are grossly overstated.[xl]  Some funds will be removed from super rather than suffer the new tax, and they will not move as Treasury assumes to higher-taxed investments. Rather, they will be spent or move to equally low- or lower-taxed alternatives.

By far the worse damage, however, is not to revenue estimates. It is to trust in the Australian superannuation system, trust in government and ultimately to the idea of government legitimacy.

10.  Is $1.6 million a defensible cap?

While the key question about the transfer balance cap is ‘why have it at all?’, many are concerned about its level.

While $1.6 million is a lot of money to many, that mainly reflects unawareness of the actuarial cost of sustaining a reasonable income over some 30 or more years of retirement. Jeremy Cooper has estimated that the actuarial value of the aged pension for a married couple is over $1 million.

The brutal reality is a fair price for an age pension in today’s interest rate environment is about $1 million. For that amount, a couple will get $1297 a fortnight, or $33,717 of income a year. That’s right; the full age pension (including supplements) would cost a 65-year-old couple a surprising $1,022,000 to buy today. For a 65-year old single woman, an age pension-equivalent income stream of $860 a fortnight for life, including supplements, or $22,365 a year, would cost $666,000.An important point to remember is the age pension is a safety net for those without the means to support themselves with dignity in retirement. A comfortable retirement would cost more.[xli]

With lower interest rates today and in prospect, the actuarial cost of the aged pension would be higher than Cooper’s 2015 million dollar estimate.  That is for a modest retirement income standard, but one indexed against inflation, protected from the ‘longevity risk’ that one might outlive one’s savings, conferring a range of valuable fringe benefits, and enjoying relatively strong political protection against un-grandfathered future reductions.

In contrast, the self-funded retiree has to save to offset longevity risk, probably low market returns, inflation, and the now considerable risk of future un-grandfathered tax increases. A couple retiring today at age 65 with $1.6 million between them can expect an indexed annual retirement income of  some $72,700 (from age 65 until age 100, with part pension from age 82, assuming an optimistic  5% return net of fees and 3% inflation).[xlii]  This is about  90% of average weekly earnings.  To retire on AWE hardly seems an indecent aspiration, especially if it motivates those who are hard working and thrifty to forgo easier aspirations to rely on a part age pension.

As mentioned above, Tony Negline illustrates that for a married couple there is severely diminishing returns from saving more than about $340,000 in super, as that amount maximizes the combined retirement income from a super pension and a part age pension. One could save almost 5 times more to reach the super target of $1.6 million and only gain a little more than twice the retirement income.[xliii] The Government’s measures to force saving above $1.6 million back into the accumulation phase paying 15% tax will further weight the trade-off against self-reliance and saving in super.

11.  Complexity and risk for the taxpayer: the case for safeguards

The exposure draft explanatory materials note that the concept of the  ‘retirement phase’ of super is colloquially well established, but now will be formally re-defined and incorporated into the taxation law.[xliv]  Unfortunately, this change causes huge complexity and uncertainty, violating the sixth of the Government’s stated objectives for super.

The Commissioner of Taxation is empowered to exercise draconian powers to compel super funds to reduce the saver’s lawfully-established retirement living standards by moving a saver’s funds from a retirement account to an accumulation account.  After an initial grace period, the Commissioner can apply severe penalties in the form of an excess transfer balance tax of up to 30% on anyone over their personal transfer balance limit. The revenue assumes notional earnings on any excess transfer balance of the daily interest of the 90-day bank bill yield plus 7 percentage points, compounding daily. Penalty taxes will be based on that formula. Compare that with what super accounts actually earn in the era where savers face ‘return-free risk’. Compare it too with the general advice to self-funded retirees that their portfolios should be low risk and oriented to fixed interest instruments (now yielding about zero real return, and in increasing cases overseas, negative nominal rates, rather than growth).[xlv]

Any well-informed and cautious taxpayer with superannuation incomes from more than one source in retirement and making a close reading of draft would be left mystified as to what his or her personal transfer balance might actually be. (Some 40% of super savers have more than one account, and 8% have more than four.) In one passing acknowledgment of the complexity, the Bill specifies that excess transfer balance tax cannot be self-assessed.[xlvi]

Legislation should require the Commissioner to issue to each retired person in receipt of superannuation income a legally binding statement of their personal transfer balance cap six months before the legislation comes into effect, and six months before the end of every financial year thereafter.  Otherwise there is an indefensible imbalance of risk and cost between the revenue and the taxpayer: the Government can make up new laws with any degree of complexity, uncertainty and compliance cost, and the taxpayer bears the risk of trying to comply with them.

12.  Bereavement

Proposed treatment of reversionary super streams on death of one partner are complex and unfair to the bereaved party. [xlvii]  It is unrealistic to believe a 6 month decision time after a partner’s death is sufficient, as would be clear to anyone who had ever experienced the time taken to secure probate on even a simple deceased estate.

13.  Treatment of defined benefit retirement income streams

The proposed increased taxes on various types of defined benefit schemes to achieve ‘broadly commensurate treatment’ with other tax increases on high balances in other funds is one of the most complex areas of the proposed measures.

The proposals try to grapple with the many historical varieties of defined benefit schemes, most (but not all) unfunded by contributions from the (mostly) government employers that set up such schemes in the medium to distant past. The schemes have generally restricted opportunities to commute pensions into lump sums – ie, they are oriented to providing whole-of-life retirement income rather than the big world tour, which many critics seem to resent. This fact (and the fact that they are unfunded by governments) means they are not amenable to the Government’s preferred approach of forcing assets over $1.6 million supporting retirement income back into an accumulation account. When tax-paid super pensions paid to the over-60s were made tax-free in the 2005 Costello simplification, defined benefit pensions were made taxable at full marginal rates on the whole pension, reduced by a 10% tax offset.

Almost all defined benefit ‘untaxed’ schemes were closed to new members some time ago (a quarter century ago, in the case of the CSS and over a decade ago in the case of the PSS).[xlviii]

If the Government grandfathered its policy to increase tax on those already retired and receiving tax-free benefits from taxed funds with assets above $1.6 million supporting their pensions, it would be unnecessary to grapple with the ‘broadly commensurate’ treatment of defined benefit schemes.  Grandfathering the Budget measures on taxed funds would remove the complex issue of how to treat defined benefit schemes – the issue would die away with the defined benefit scheme’s beneficiaries. Bygones are bygones, and not a useful guide to tomorrow’s policy choice.

A third point of interest is that there are a lot of ‘moving parts’ in the Government’s proposals for increased taxes on defined benefit schemes.

As far as can be determined form the Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials, the tax offset for untaxed defined benefit schemes would be capped at a pension of $100,000 p.a.; the value of any pension of $100,000 or more would be deemed to have a value of ($100,000 * 16), so any pension with capped tax offset would be valued at a transfer balance of $1.6 million, thereby exhausting the balance cap of the retiree.

Any additional savings such a retiree might have made in any other super fund are immediately declared excess to the retiree’s personal transfer balance cap. So any additional super savings are immediately forced out of the retirement phase and their earnings taxed at 15% in an accumulation fund.

Finally, any pension over $100,000 p.a would have half of the excess over $100,000 added to the pensioner’s annual income and taxed at the beneficiary’s top marginal rate.This is potentially a triple jeopardy for defined benefit super pensioners, and it is not immediately clear if the three increases combined are more or less commensurate with the increased taxes on other high-transfer balance self-funded retirees.

The Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials notes that important issues for significant numbers of defined benefit retirees are still not resolved.[xlix] It invites  comments on how these unresolved issues that have defeated policy advisers for four months may be addressed — something not possible within the short time allowed for public consultation.

14.  Lower minimum drawdown amounts on super pensions

The tranche two measures take effect when global growth prospects are poor, advanced economy growth is still falling, and many interest rates are near-zero or negative in real terms.[l]

Those nearing retirement and self-funded retirees are commonly advised to stick to low-risk portfolios of fixed interest and similar products, and re-weight portfolios away from potential growth assets with high volatility such as domestic and foreign equities. But now they grapple with an era of ‘return-free risk’ and still have to withdraw a minimum amount of from 4 to 14% a year (rising with age) under the legal requirements that have to be met for retirement annuities to enjoy a tax exemption for the investment earnings of the super fund assets (below their personal transfer balance cap) supporting them. [li] In a ‘return-free risk’ environment, these drawdown requirements amount to a rule for accelerating real decline in retirement phase super balances.  Put differently, they add to encouragements to stop saving and go for the part aged pension.

The Budget tax increases will further reduce living standards of those affected, adding to the squeeze between falling market returns and minimum drawdown amounts still rising with age.

The Government should act immediately on the recommendation of the Retirement Income Streams Review to seek Australian Government Actuary recommendations for lower minimum drawdown amounts on super pensions, as were applied from 2008-09 to 2012-13.[lii]  Those recommendations should address realistic, bleak prospects for future earnings, not the past multi-decadal history of equity booms and dot-com bubbles.

15.  Innovative income streams: more costs of ‘effective retrospectivity’

Chapter 8 of the Exposure Draft Explanatory Materials in part outlines an intent to extend the earnings tax exemption that the Budget removes from those current retirement income streams arising from a transfer balance cap above $1.6 million.  The extended concession would apply to innovative lifetime products such as ‘deferred products’ and ‘group self-annuities’ that may emerge in the future. Such products, were savers ever to demand them, would permit a belated start to pension payments, thereby possibly addressing savers’ need to manage longevity risk.[liii]

For example, a super saver aged 55 in 2017 could purchase a ‘deferred pension’ that commences at age 80.  Legislation in 2017 would provide an earnings tax exemption on the funds supporting that pension from the date the saver satisfies a condition of release, such as attaining the age of 65 in 2027 (para 8.35). Then the retiree would gain tax-free income from the deferred annuity in 2042.  The assets supporting the annuity would by then be larger than otherwise by the compounding of 15 years’ earnings growth since 2027 with no tax on the earnings.

In a world where the Government is withdrawing with ‘effective retrospectivity’ the earnings tax exemption on assets already lawfully saved over a lifetime, and destroying a tax-free annuity under existing law to those already retired, why would anyone buy a deferred annuity that would not start payment until a quarter-century in the future?  That would merely provide the next 8 governments with 25 years in which to withdraw the new tax concession with ‘effective retrospectivity’.

When a future government withdraws without grandfathering the ‘deferred pension’ concession of 2017, they could cite the precedent of the Turnbull/Morrison Budget of May 2016; they could say that the super concessions were too expensive, too unfair and unsustainable; argue that 95% or 99% of people would not be adversely affected; and that the only losers were already very old, wouldn’t need much money at that stage of life, and could access the age pension if they needed to.

This problem underlines a dilemma created by the Budget measures.  The Government can only offer facilitating a decrease in longevity risk at the same time as it has increased the regulatory risk of future ‘effectively retrospective’ law changes.  The net effect is zero, or worse.

The example illustrates the unbounded damage caused by increasing super tax without grandfathering.  Any government’s ability to induce or facilitate a desired objective depends on citizens trusting that it will play fair, abide by its own laws, and change them only with prospective effect.  When a government destroys trust, it destroys all plausible influence on future developments that depend on keeping its word.

16.  Conclusions

By destroying confidence in super through ‘effectively retrospective’ changes, the proposed measures re-weight Australians’ retirement planning towards smaller super balances and higher reliance on a part age pension.

The time allowed for public consultation on the Government’s complex measures is derisorily short.  History has shown that rushed and ill-considered super changes lead to spiraling complexity and the need for additional changes to correct unintended consequences.

The Government should take its second tranche measures back to the drawing board, along with the first tranche of new super tax expenditures, and the unworkable statement of objectives for superannuation.

The Government should bring forward a quantified and transparent statement of the net effect of its preferred measures on the retirement living standards of Australians and on retirement policy costs (both superannuation and age pension) to the budget. The evaluation should use a sensible recasting of the presently unworkable Superannuation (Objective) Bill 2016, and should demonstrably meet the requirements of the recast Bill.

The Government should review the misleading but ubiquitous estimate of the high cost of superannuation concessions, and switch to a conceptually defensible measure such as illustrated by Treasury’s 2013 ‘experimental estimate’ of super concession costs.  It should address the suggestions in the reports by the Henry tax review and the Cooper Charter Group that when appropriately measured in net terms (ie allowing for the reduction in age pension costs, if only from reduced access to the full pension ) the costs of superannuation concessions may be very small or even negative.

The Government should contest the view that use of superannuation concessions is unfair, because allegedly regressive.  In fact, use of super concessions is roughly proportionate to super savers’ contribution by decile to overall income tax collections.

The Government should contest the view that ‘fairness’ is a one-dimensional construct  requiring redistribution from anyone richer to anyone poorer, to be achieved by conscripting every aspect of every policy until reaching the only logical end point, complete equality. It should emphasise that ‘fairness’ includes ideals of fair reward for effort and fair reward for thrift, leading to self-sufficiency, and reducing dependence on the state and the taxes of one’s fellow citizens.  Fairness also involves keeping one’s commitments. To be fair, governments should keep their commitments. Redistributive fairness is certainly also important, but should be judged by the overall progressiveness of the tax and transfer system, which is already very high in Australia.

If the proposed legislation is passed by the House of Representatives, the Senate should subject it to careful scrutiny. It should refer the whole of the Government’s proposed superannuation package to a Senate Committee. The Senate Committee should invite and consider public submissions and objections.

The package should include appropriate grandfathering provisions. That would maintain the sound practice of at least the last 40 years of changes in Australian super law, and maintain trust in superannuation.

[i] The term ‘effective retrospectivity’ was coined by Scott Morrison, Address to the SMSF 2016 National Conference, Adelaide, 18 February 2016. See quote on title page.  The term captures the essence of the problem caused by the Budget measures for retirees and those near retirement, and is used consistently in the remainder of this submission.

[ii] Scott Morrison, Treasury Laws Amendment (Fair and sustainable superannuation) bill 2016: exposure draft explanatory materials, Canberra October 2016.  See especially paras 1.172and 1.227.

[iii] Peter Costello, A Plan to Simplify and Streamline Superannuation: Detailed Outline, Canberra, May 2006

[iv] Peter Costello, Simplified Superannuation – Final Decisions, Press Release 093 , 5 September 2006

[v] Scott Morrison and Kelly O’Dwyer, Superannuation reforms: first tranche of Exposure Drafts , 7 September 2016

[vi]   Scott Morrison, Superannuation (Objective) Bill 2016, Explanatory Materials, p6, para 1.16

[vii] Peter Costello, A Plan to Simplify and Streamline Superannuation: Detailed Outline, Canberra, May 2006, p 1

[viii] John Roskam, The Turnbull Government Backs An Unprincipled Purpose Of Super, 9 September 2016,

[ix] Terrence O’Brien, Submission on First Tranche of Superannuation Exposure Drafts, 16 September 2016

[x] Tony Negline, Saving or slaving: find the sweet spot for super, The Australian, 4 October 2016.

[xi] Terrence O’Brien, Grandfathering super tax increases, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy, Vol. 32 No. 3 (Spring, 2016), pp3-12

[xii] Terrence O’Brien, Examination of proposed super changes, letter of   7 September 2016 to Government members.

[xiii] Terrence O’Brien, ibid.

[xiv] Robert Menzies, The Forgotten People, 22 May 1942

[xv] Kelly O’Dwyer, Dispelling myths perpetuated by base politicking, The Australian, 10 May 2016.

[xvi] Swoboda, K., Major superannuation and retirement income changes in Australia: a chronology, Parliamentary Library Research paper Series 2013-14, Attachment 2, 11 March 2014

[xvii]Peter Costello, Tax Laws Amendment (Simplified Superannuation) Bill 2006, Explanatory Memorandum, C2006B00226.

[xviii] Peter Costello, footnote 7 above, section 1.2

[xix] Scot Morrison and Mathias Cormann, Budget Measures, Budget Paper No 2,  2016-17, 3 May 2016, p 25

[xx] Australian Taxation Office[xxi] Robert Cincotta of Anderson Partners, Chartered Accountants, estimates that the extra annual compliance cost for Self Managed Superannuation Funds affected by the proposed new superannuation law will be approximately $3,000 to $4,000, depending on the circumstances of each Self Managed Superannuation Fund.

[xxii] Tracy Oliver and Scott Bartley, Tax system complexity and compliance costs — some theoretical considerations, Treasury Economic Roundup, winter 2005.

[xxiii] Scott Morrison, Superannuation (Objective) Bill 2016, Explanatory Materials, p6, para 1.16.

[xxiv] Scott Morrison and Kelly O’Dwyer, Even Fairer, More Flexible and Sustainable Superannuation, Media Statement, 15 September 2016.

[xxv] Ken Henry et al, Australia’s future tax system, Report to the Treasurer, Part Two, Detailed analysis, Volume 1, December 2009, p 12.

[xxvi] Simon Cowan,  The Myths of the Generational Bargain, Centre for Independent Studies, Research Report 10, 1 March 2016.

[xxvii] Scott Morrison, Address to the SMSF 2016 National Conference, Adelaide, 18 February 2016.

Many of you know that there are different ways to measure the size of these concessions; I know ASPRA (sic) in particular take some exception to the way tax expenditures statements are used or, I should say, abused by some in this debate. Tax expenditure statements do not represent costings. They do not truly reflect what the cost to revenue actually is and the way they are combined also inappropriately by some advocates, particularly the Opposition, misrepresents the cost to the Government in what amounts to expenditures that are provided in tax concessions. I think this is an area that we can continue to refine and get right and ASPRA has some excellent suggestions about how we might achieve to do that, as does the SMSF Association. We hope to achieve that together with all of the organisations in the sector. They don’t, these tax expenditures statements, represent the potential revenue gain to the Government as many have claimed.

Some say these concessions are as high as $30 billion. Others believe it could be as low as $11 billion. The task is to weigh up the value of superannuation tax concessions against other uses for how that revenue might be applied.

In fact, these two numbers are not just ‘beliefs’; they are both Treasury estimates.  The first uses a comprehensive income tax as a hypothetical benchmark, and the second uses one of several valid expenditure tax benchmarks. Both numbers are gross, not allowing for savings from reduced access to the age pension induced by the concessions.

[xxviii] Robert Carling, Right or Rort? Dissecting Australia’s Tax Concessions, Centre for Independent Studies, Research Report 2, April 2015.

[xxix]Mark Day, Tax cuts: A lesson for Duncan Storrar and Q&A,  The Australian, 16 May 2016.

[xxx] Scott Morrison, Address to the SMSF 2016 National Conference, Adelaide, 18 February 2016.

[xxxi] Robert Carling, How should super be taxed?, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy,  Vol. 32 No. 3 (Spring, 2016), p 20,

[xxxii] A classic example is the Green’s superannuation policy that concessional (i.e. pre-tax) contributions to super, presently taxed at a flat 15%, should instead be taxed at progressive rates of up to 32%.  Moreover, there should also be a welfare payment: anyone earning below the tax–free threshold of $18,200 and locking away savings in super for 40 years (hello – anyone there?) should receive a payment from other taxpayers of 15c for every dollar they save.

On the progressiveness of Australia’s tax/benefit system, see Dick Warburton and Peter Hendy, International comparison of Australia’s taxes, April 2006, Section 4.5.

[xxxiii] Terrence O’Brien, Grandfathering super tax increases, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy, Vol. 32 No. 3 (Spring, 2016), pp4-6.

[xxxiv] Scott Morrison, Address to the SMSF 2016 National Conference, Adelaide, 18 February 2016.

[xxxv] Ross Gittins, A light on the hill for our future tax reformers, The Age 15 June 2009.

[xxxvi] Jeremy Cooper, A Super Charter: Fewer Changes, Better Outcomes: A report to the Treasurer and Minister Assisting for Financial Services and Superannuation, Canberra, 5 July 2013.

[xxxvii] Jeremy Cooper, ibid, p 16.

[xxxviii] Terrence O’Brien, Grandfathering super tax increases, Centre for Independent Studies, Policy, Vol. 32 No. 3 (Spring, 2016), pp3-12.

[xxxix] Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Political Legitimacy, revised 13 May 2016.

[xl] Terrence O’Brien, Examination of proposed super changes, letter of   7 September 2016 to Government members.

[xli] Jeremy Cooper, Before super tax changes, remember the pension is worth $1 million, Australian Financial Review, 19 April 2015.

[xlii] Trish Power, Crunching the numbers: a $1.6 million retirement, SuperGuide, 23 May 2016.

[xliii] Tony Negline, Saving or slaving: find the sweet spot for super, The Australian, 4 October 2016.

[xliv] Scott Morrison, Treasury Laws Amendment (Fair and sustainable superannuation) bill 2016: exposure draft explanatory materials, Canberra October 2016, p 14 para 1.31

[xlv] Scott Morrison, ibid, p 19.

[xlvi] Scott Morrison, ibid, p 67, para 1.259.

[xlvii] Scott Morrison, ibid,  p 18.

[xlviii] Anne Willenborg, Annette Barbetti and Trevor Nock , How the CSS and PSS work, SCOA SuperTime Newsletter, May 2014.

[xlix] Scott Morrison, op cit, para 1.172 p46.

[l] International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook: Subdued Demand: Symptoms and Remedies, October 2016.

[li] Trish Power, Minimum pension payments for 2015/16 and 2017/17 years, SuperGuide, 17 May 2016.

[lii] The Treasury, Retirement Income Streams Review, Canberra, 3 May 2016.

[liii] Superannuation (Objective) Bill 2016, Explanatory Materials, ibid, pp 102-109, especially para 8.35

The $1.6 million transfer balance cap explained

By William Fettes (wfettes@dbalawyers.com.au), Lawyer, DBA Lawyers, Bryce Figot (bfigot@dbalawyers.com.au), Director, DBA Lawyers and Daniel Butler, Director, DBA Lawyers (dbutler@dbalawyers.com.au)

Introduction

The Department of Treasury on 27 September 2016 released the second tranche of exposure draft legislation and explanatory material in relation to the Federal Government’s proposed superannuation reforms.

These materials provide long-awaited detail on the workings of the $1.6 million transfer balance cap measure. This article explains some key take-away points about this measure.

The transfer balance cap and transfer balance account

Broadly, the $1.6 million balance cap measure is a limit imposed on the total amount that a member can transfer into a tax-free pension phase account from 1 July 2017.

The general transfer balance cap is $1.6 million for the 2017-18 financial year subject to indexation (see below for further information on the indexation rules).

An individual’s personal transfer balance cap is linked to the general transfer balance cap. All fund members who are in receipt of a pension on 1 July 2017 will have a personal balance cap of $1.6 million established at that time. Otherwise, a fund member’s personal balance cap comes into existence when they first become entitled to a pension. An individual’s personal transfer balance cap is equal to the general balance cap for the relevant financial year in which their personal balance cap commenced.

Usage of personal cap space will be determined by the total value of superannuation assets supporting existing pension liabilities for a member on 1 July 2017, as well as the capital value of any pensions commenced or received by a member from 1 July 2017 onwards.

A member’s available cap capacity over time is subject to a system of debits and credits recorded in a ‘transfer balance account’, which is a kind of ledger whereby amounts transferred into pension phase are credited to the account and amounts commuted or rolled-over are debited from the account.

Earnings and capital growth on assets supporting pension liabilities are ignored when applying the personal transfer balance cap. Thus, a member’s personal balance cap may grow beyond the $1.6 million cap due to earnings and growth without resulting in an excess. As such, a taxpayer who allocates growth or higher yielding assets to their balance cap will generally be better off if their pension assets appreciate in value. However, note the limitations with regards to the segregation method discussed below.

Any amounts in excess of a member’s personal transfer balance cap can continue to be maintained in their accumulation account in the superannuation system. Thus, members with superannuation account balances greater than $1.6 million can maintain up to $1.6 million in pension phase and retain any additional balance in accumulation phase.

What counts as a credit?

The following items count as a credit towards an individual’s transfer balance account and thereby their personal transfer balance cap:

  • the value of all assets supporting pension liabilities in respect of a member on 30 June 2017;
  • the capital value of new pensions commenced from 1 July 2017;
  • the capital value of reversionary pensions at the time the individual becomes entitled to them (subject to modified balance cap rules for reversionary pensions to children); and
  • notional earnings that accrue on excess transfer balance amounts.

As can be seen from the above list, death benefit pensions count towards to the recipient’s personal transfer balance cap.

The inclusion of death benefit pensions as part of the reversionary beneficiary’s transfer balance cap is in accordance with DBA Lawyers’ prediction in our 1 August 2016 newsfeed article. This aspect will have a significant impact on the succession plans of all fund members who collectively with their spouse have more than $1.6 million in superannuation.

Fortunately, there is an important concession. An excess will only occur as a result of a death benefit pension six months from the date that the reversionary beneficiary becomes entitled to receive the pension. This means there is a grace period for reversionary beneficiaries to commute their pension interest(s) to stay within their personal transfer balance cap without triggering any excess. The exposure draft explanatory memorandum (‘EM’) explains the six month period as follows:

This gives the new beneficiary sufficient time to adjust their affairs following the death of a relative before any consequences – for example, a breach of their transfer balance cap – arise.

Typically, a surviving spouse suffers years of grieving following the loss of a spouse but only has a six month period to make a decision on a reversionary pension if that results in an excess of their personal transfer balance cap.

What counts as a debit?

A member’s transfer balance account is debited when they commute (partially or fully) the capital of a pension. When a commutation occurs, the debit entry to the transfer balance account is equal to the amount commuted. Accordingly, it is possible for an individual’s transfer balance account to have a negative balance if their debits exceed their credits. For example, a full commutation of a pension where the assets supporting that pension have grown from $1.6 million to $1.7 million will result in a transfer balance account of negative $100,000.

Ordinary pension payments do not count as debit entries for the purposes of the transfer balance account. Proposed legislative amendments will ensure that partial commutations do not count towards prescribed minimum pension payments. This proposal may also impact a member with an account-based pension electing to convert an amount to a lump sum for claiming their low rate cap.

In addition to the above recognised debits, relief will be available in relation to certain events where an individual loses some or all of the value of assets that are held in pension phase. The proposed relief concerns family law payment splits, fraud and void transactions under the Bankruptcy Act 1966 (Cth). In these circumstances, an individual will be able to apply to the ATO for relief so that their transfer balance account can be debited to restore their personal transfer balance cap, eg, if a member is defrauded of their super savings and the perpetrator is convicted, then a debit (or restoration) can be made to their transfer balance account.

At this stage, there is no relief proposed in relation to a major economic downturn eroding the value of fund assets held in pension phase. Therefore, if another global financial crisis were to occur, any adverse economic effects on the assets supporting pensions could substantially impair a member’s personal transfer balance cap.

Excess personal transfer balance cap

Individuals who exceed their personal transfer balance cap will have their superannuation income streams commuted (in full or in part) back into accumulation phase and notional earnings (see below) on the excess will be subject to an excess transfer balance tax.

Notional earnings accrue on excess transfer balances based on the general interest charge. Notional earnings accrue daily until the breach is rectified and are generally credited towards an individual’s transfer balance account (subject to a transfer balance determination being made by the Commissioner).

The draft EM provides the following example of an excess transfer balance (refer to example 1.14):

On 1 July 2017, Rebecca commences a superannuation income stream of $1 million from the superannuation fund her employer contributed to (Master Superannuation Fund). On 1 October 2017, Rebecca also commences a $1 million superannuation income stream in her SMSF, Bec’s Super Fund.

On 1 July 2017, Rebecca’s transfer balance account is $1 million. On 1 October 2017, Rebecca’s transfer balance is credited with a further $1 million bringing her transfer balance account to $2 million. This means that Rebecca has an excess transfer balance of $400,000.

On 15 October 2017, the Commissioner issues an excess transfer balance determination to Rebecca setting out a crystallised reduction amount of $401,414 (excess of $400,000 plus 14 days of notional earnings). Included with the determination is a default commutation authority which lets Rebecca know that if she does not make an election within 60 days of the determination date the Commissioner will issue a commutation authority to Bec’s Super Fund requiring the trustee to commute her $1 million superannuation income stream by $401,414.

As can be seen from the above example, there is some flexibility built into the system for proactive rectification where an excess transfer balance occurs.

An excess transfer balance tax is payable on the accrued notional earnings of the excess amount to neutralise any benefit received from having excess capital in the tax-free retirement phase. The excess transfer balance tax is assessed for the financial year in which a member breaches their transfer balance cap. The excess transfer balance tax is 15% on notional earnings for the first breach and 30% for second and subsequent breaches.

Indexation of the balance cap

The transfer balance cap is indexed in increments of $100,000 on an annual basis in line with the Consumer Price Index.

A person’s eligibility to receive indexation increases in relation to their personal transfer balance cap is subject to a proportioning formula based on the highest balance of the member’s transfer balance account compared to the member’s personal balance cap.

The proportioning formula as applied to an example increase of $100,000 is as follows:

(Personal transfer balance cap – highest transfer balance) x $100,000
Personal transfer balance cap

 

An example of how the proportioning formula applies in practice is set out below.

Example

John commences a pension with an account balance of $800,000 in FY2017-18. At that time, he has used 50% of his $1.6 million personal transfer balance cap.

If the general transfer balance cap is indexed to $1.7 million in 2019-20, John’s personal transfer balance cap is increased by $50,000 because he is only eligible to take 50% of the $100,000 increase. Accordingly, John can now commence a pension with capital of $850,000 without breaching his personal transfer balance cap.

The above answer does not change if John partially commutes his pension prior to the indexation increase, as the formula is based on John’s highest transfer balance (ie, $800,000).

A member who has exhausted or exceeded their personal transfer balance cap will not be eligible for any cap indexation.

CGT relief

The draft legislation also provides CGT relief which broadly enables the cost base of assets reallocated from pension to accumulation phase to be refreshed to comply with the transfer balance cap or the new transition to retirement income stream arrangements. The draft EM states:

Complying superannuation funds will now be able to reset the cost base of assets that are reallocated from the retirement phase to the accumulation phase prior to 1 July 2017.

Where these assets are already partially supporting accounts in the accumulation phase, tax will be paid on this proportion of the capital gain made to 1 July 2017. This tax may be deferred until the asset is sold, for up to 10 years.

Segregated assets

Broadly, an SMSF trustee can elect to obtain CGT relief to reset the cost base of a segregated asset to its market value provided the asset ceases to be a segregated asset prior to 1 July 2017. The market value is determined ‘just before’ the time the asset ceased being a segregated current pension asset.

Typically, an asset would cease to be segregated by being transferred from pension to accumulation phase. However, it appears that an asset could also cease being segregated by being treated as an unsegregated asset (with an associated actuarial report).

It is important to note, however, that the segregation method will not be available to SMSFs and small APRA funds, with at least one member in pension mode who has a total superannuation fund balance of over $1.6 million (in all funds). This limits planning opportunities that may otherwise be available to SMSFs under the segregation method.

Unsegregated or proportionate assets

Broadly, where an asset is supporting a pension liability using the unsegregated or proportionate method, an SMSF trustee can elect to obtain CGT relief to reset the cost base of an asset to its market value on 1 July 2017 subject to the following requirements:

  • the fund must calculate a notional gain on the proportion of the asset that is effectively attributable to the accumulation phase as at 30 June 2017;
  • if not deferred, the fund must add this notional gain to its net capital gain (or loss) for FY2017 which effectively crystallises the tax liability that would have arisen if that asset had been sold in FY2017;
  • however, an SMSF trustee can elect to defer the notional gain for up to 10 years (ie, up to 1 July 2027) unless a realisation event occurs earlier than 1 July 2027; and
  • if a realisation event does not occur by 1 July 2027, the cost base of the relevant asset will revert to its original cost base.

If the relevant asset is sold before 1 July 2027, the deferred notional gain is added to any further net capital gain (or adjusted against any net capital loss) made on a realisation event such as the ultimate sale of that asset. This further notional gain is calculated based on the higher cost base determined as at 30 June 2017 (being the market value of that asset at 30 June 2017 with any further adjustments to that asset’s cost base since 30 June 2017).

Thus, an SMSF trustee may elect to reset the cost base of an asset. This election may be applied on an asset by asset basis as some may prefer not to reset the cost base of all eligible assets to market value, eg, a particular asset’s market value may be lower than its cost base and a cost base reset in that context could result in a greater future capital gain. Further, this election can be made in the SMSF’s FY2017 annual return and does not need to be made prior to 1 July 2017 (as is the case for a CGT reset for a segregated asset as discussed above).

The net capital gain attributable to the accumulation interest that is not exempt under the exempt current pension income provisions is taxed at 15% subject to the 1/3 CGT discount available for assets held for more than 12 months. Refer to examples 1.45, 1.46 and 1.47 in the draft EM.

Although the prospect of resetting the cost base of current pension assets may be attractive in the lead up to 1 July 2017, paragraph 1.226 of the draft EM reminds SMSF trustees not to overlook the general anti-avoidance provisions in part IVA of the Income Tax Assessment Act 1936 (Cth). This paragraph of the EM states:

The CGT relief arrangements are only intended to support movements of assets and balances necessary to support the transfer balance cap and changes to the TRIS. It would be otherwise inappropriate for a fund to wash assets to obtain CGT relief or to use the relief to reduce the income tax payable on existing assets supporting the accumulation phase. Schemes designed to maximise an entity’s CGT relief or to minimise the CGT gains of existing assets in accumulation phase may be subject to the general anti-avoidance rules in Part IVA …

Naturally, the impact of the CGT reset provisions will need to be carefully considered as there are numerous strategies that will unfold under the draft proposals.

Conclusions

The proposed $1.6 million transfer balance cap measure involves substantial changes to Australia’s superannuation system, especially the tracking of each member’s personal balance cap. The balance cap proposal will reduce the tax effectiveness of pensions due to the new cap and have a major impact on succession planning strategies giving rise to substantially more tax payable overall in respect of death.

In particular, many couples will not like the fact that their deceased spouse’s reversionary pension gets ‘retested’ to a surviving spouse where the surviving spouse is subject to only their own $1.6 million personal balance cap. The Government has seen that raising extra tax revenue is preferred rather than allowing a deceased spouse’s pension that would have already been tested within their personal transfer balance cap to revert to a surviving spouse. We see this as a major issue that is likely to arise in submissions.

Note that the above commentary is a general summary only based on exposure draft legislation and explanatory material that is subject to change. For full details, see https://consult.treasury.gov.au/retirement-income-policy-division/super-reform-package-tranche-2

Related articles

http://www.dbalawyers.com.au/pensions/automatically-reversionary-pensions-super-reform/

http://www.dbalawyers.com.au/announcements/proposed-superannuation-reforms-july-2016/

http://www.dbalawyers.com.au/announcements/1-6m-balance-cap-examined-tax-death-benefits/

*           *           *

This article is for general information only and should not be relied upon without first seeking advice from an appropriately qualified professional.

Note: DBA Lawyers hold SMSF CPD training at venues all around. For more details or to register, visit www.dbanetwork.com.au or call 03 9092 9400.

For more information regarding how DBA Lawyers can assist in your SMSF practice, visit www.dbalawyers.com.au.

DBA LAWYERS

4 October 2016

Budget 2016 superannuation proposals which should be grandfathered – update

As from 27 September 2016, the current Budget 2016 superannuation proposals include:

  • the introduction of a transfer balance cap of $1.6 million on amounts into the tax-free retirement (pension) phase from 1 July 2017.
  • after commencement, if individuals already in retirement as at 1 July 2017 retain balances in excess of the $1.6 million cap and do not transfer the excess out of the retirement phase account, an excess transfer balance tax will be payable;
  • introduction of commensurate measures to defined benefit arrangements;
  • removal of the tax exemption on earnings which support Transition to Retirement Income (pension) streams.

Load more